Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Advertisements

Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western What’s Important in Chapter 15 Sources of Monopolies (= Price Makers = Market.
Chapter 12 Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
12 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Monopoly.
MBMC Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition.
1 Frank & Bernanke 3 rd edition, 2007 Ch. 10: Ch. 10: Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Monopoly u A monopoly is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not.
Ch. 12: Monopoly Causes of monopoly
15 Monopoly.
Monopoly - Characteristics
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
Ch. 12: Monopoly  Causes of monopoly  Monopoly pricing and output determination  Performance and efficiency of single-price monopoly and competition.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. its.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Monopoly u A monopoly is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not.
Monopoly ECO 230 J.F. O’Connor. Market Structure Perfect Competition –participants act as price takers and cannot by individual behavior affect market.
 Firm that is sole seller of product without close substitutes  Price Maker not a Price Taker  There are barriers to entry thru: Monopoly Resources,
Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics, 9e Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice.
Chapter 12: Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
Copyright © 2010, All rights reserved eStudy.us Market Structure – A classification system for the key traits of a market, including.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2009 The McGraw-Hill Companies, All Rights Reserved Chapter 8 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition.
MBMC Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition.
Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition
Copyright©2004 South-Western Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Monopoly ETP Economics 101. Monopoly  A firm is considered a monopoly if...  it is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not have close.
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 7. Monopoly Prof. Vera Adamchik.
MONOPOLY Why do monopolies arise? Why is MR < P for a monopolist?
Monopoly Eco 2023 Chapter 10 Fall Monopoly A market with a single seller with a product that is differentiated from other products.
Chapter 22 Microeconomics Unit III: The Theory of the Firm.
1 Chapter 11: Monopoly. 2 Monopoly Assumptions: Restricted entry One firm produces a distinct product Implications: A monopolist firm is a ‘price setter,’
MONOPOLY. Monopoly Recall characteristics of a perfectly competitive market: –many buyers and sellers –market participants are “price takers” –economic.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Monopoly 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied,
10-1 Copyright  2007 McGraw-Hill Australia Pty Ltd PPTs t/a Principles of Microeconomics by Frank, Bernanke and Jennings Slides prepared by Nahid Khan.
Econ 2610: Principles of Microeconomics
Monopoly Story of NES, Comcast, even Central Parking.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 7: Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition.
MBMC Copyright c 2004 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Last word on invisible hand… There are some important projects that need.
MBMC Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power BEC Managerial Economics.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
Chapter 11 Monopoly.
Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 15 Monopoly.
Chapter Monopoly 15. In economic terms, why are monopolies bad? Explain. 2.
13 MONOPOLY. © 2012 Pearson Education A monopoly is a market:  That produces a good or service for which no close substitute exists  In which there.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Monopoly 1. Why Monopolies Arise Monopoly –Firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes –Price maker Barriers to entry –Monopoly.
Monopoly 15. Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. it is the sole seller of its product. its product does.
Monopoly CCE ECO 211 REMEDIAL. Section3.1 MONOPOLY A monopoly is a type of an imperfect market. It is a market structure in which a single seller is the.
1 Chapter 9: Imperfect Competition Imperfectly competitive firms have some control of price –Long-run economic profits possible –Reduce economic surplus.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition
Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition
Chapter 15 Monopoly.
Monopoly and imperfect competition
Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if . . .
ECN 201: Principles of Microeconomics
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Ch. 13: Monopoly Causes of monopoly
Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition
Presentation transcript:

Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition

Perfectly Competitive Market An ideal market that maximizes economic surplus A situation that does not always exist

Imperfect Competition Imperfectly Competitive Firms Have some control over price Price may be greater than the marginal cost of production Long-run economic profits are possible Reduce economic surplus to varying degrees Are very common

Forms of Imperfect Competition 1. Pure Monopoly The only supplier of a unique product with no close substitutes 2. Monopolistic Competition A large number of firms that produce slightly differentiated products that are reasonably close substitutes for one another Long-run adjustment to zero economic profits Importance of differentiation

Forms of Imperfect Competition 3. Oligopoly Industry structure in which a small number of firms produce products that are either close or perfect substitutes Cost advantages from large size may prevent the long-run adjustment to zero economic profit Undifferentiated and differentiated products

Essential Difference Between Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Firms The perfectly competitive firm faces a perfectly elastic demand for its product. The imperfectly competitive firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve.

The Demand Curves Facing Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Firms Market price $/unit of output Price D Quantity Quantity

Perfectly competitive market Supply and demand determine equilibrium price. The firm has no market power. At the equilibrium price, the firm sells all it wishes. If the firm raises its price, sales will be zero. If the firm lowers its price, sales will not increase. The firm’s demand curve is the horizontal line at the market price.

Imperfectly Competitive Markets The firm has some control over price or some market power. A firm’s ability to raise the price of a good without losing all its sales Sellers face a downward sloping demand

Sources of Market Power Exclusive control over inputs Patents and Copyrights Government Licenses or Franchises Economies of Scale (Natural Monopolies) Network Externalities

Economies of Scale and the Importance of Start-Up Costs Firms with large fixed costs and low variable costs: Have low marginal costs Average total cost declines sharply as output increases Economies of scale will exist

Costs for Two Computer Game Producers (1) Nintendo Playstation Annual production 1,000,000 1,200,000 Fixed cost $200,000 $200,000 Variable cost $800,000 $960,000 Total cost $1,000,000 $1,160,000 Average total cost per game $1.00 $0.97 Observations Fixed costs are a relatively small share of total cost Cost/game is nearly the same

Costs for Two Computer Game Producers (2) Nintendo Playstation Annual production 1,000,000 1,200,000 Fixed cost $10,000,000 $10,000,000 Variable cost $200,000 $240,000 Total cost $10,200,000 $10,240,000 Average total cost per game $10.20 $8.53 Observations Fixed costs are a relatively large share of total cost Playstation has a $1.67 average cost advantage Playstation can lower prices, cover cost, and attract customers

Costs for Two Computer Game Producers (3) Nintendo Playstation Annual production 500,000 1,700,000 Fixed cost $10,000,000 $10,000,000 Variable cost $100,000 $340,000 Total cost $10,100,000 $10,340,000 Average total cost per game $20.20 $6.08 Shift of 500,000 units to Playstation Nintendo’s average cost increases to $20.20/unit Playstation average cost falls to $6.08 A large number of firms cannot survive when the cost differential is high

Economies of Scale and the Importance of Fixed Costs Fixed investment in research and development has been increasing as a share of production costs. Cost of producing a computer Fixed Cost Variable Cost Software Hardware 1984 20% 80% 1990 80% 20%

Profit Maximization for the Monopolist A price taker (perfect competition) and a price setter (imperfect competition) share the economic goal. They want: To maximize profits; i.e., To select the output level that maximizes the difference between TR and TC, where MB= MC (when quantity is divisible and not producing at all is not optimal).

Profit Maximization for the Monopolist For a producer MB = Marginal Revenue (MR) or a change in a firm’s total revenue that results from a one-unit change in output

Profit Maximization for the Monopolist Marginal Revenue for the Monopolist Perfect competition and monopolies Both increase output when MR > MC. Calculate MC the same way. Do not have the same MR at a given price. In perfect competition: MR = P In monopoly: MR < P

The Monopolist’s Benefit from Selling an Additional Unit 8 If P = $6, then TR = $6 x 2 = $12 If P = $5, then TR = $5 x 3 = $15 The MR of selling the 3rd unit = $3 (=15-12) For the 3rd unit, MR = $3 < P = $5 6 5 Price ($/unit) D 2 3 8 Quantity (units/week)

Marginal Revenue in Graphical Form Observations MR < P MR declines as quantity increases MR is the change between two quantities MR < P because price must be lowered to sell an additional unit P Q TR MR 6 2 12 5 3 15 4 16 3 1 -1 Slide 20

Marginal Revenue in Graphical Form Price & marginal revenue ($/unit) Quantity (units/week) 8 D 4 3 2 -1 5 1 MR P Q TR MR 6 2 12 5 3 15 4 16 3 1 -1

The Marginal Revenue Curve for a Monopolist with a Straight-Line Demand Curve Price a/2 D MR Q0/2 Q0 Quantity Observations The vertical intercept, a, is the same for MR and D The horizontal intercept for MR, Q0/2, is one half the demand intercept, Q0.

Profit Maximization for the Monopolist Profit Maximizing Decision Rule When MR > MC, output should be increased. When MR < MC, output should be reduced. Profits are maximized at the level of output for which MR = MC.

The Monopolist’s Profit- Maximizing Output Level Marginal Cost 6 Observations If P = $3 & Q = 12, MR < MC and output should reduce Profits are maximized at 8 units where MR = MC P = $4 where quantity demanded = quantity supplied 4 Price ($/unit of output) 3 2 D MR 8 12 24 Quantity (units/week)

Even a Monopolist May Suffer an Economic Loss Being a monopolist doesn’t guarantee an economic profit Economic loss = $400,000/day Economic profit = $400,000/day 0.12 0.10 0.10 ATC 0.08 Price ($/minute) Price ($/minute) ATC MC 0.05 MC 0.05 D D 20 MR 20 MR 24 Minutes (millions/day) Minutes (millions/day)

The Demand and Marginal Cost Curves for a Monopolist Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down Under Monopoly D 3 12 6 24 Marginal cost The socially optimal amount occurs where MC = D(=MB) @ 12 units Price ($/unit of output) Quantity (units/week)

Price ($/unit of output) Quantity (units/week) The Demand and Marginal Cost Curves for a Monopolist Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down Under Monopoly 6 Marginal cost 2 4 MR 8 The profit maximizing level of output of 8 units, where MR = MC, is less than the socially optimal output of 12 Between 8 and 12, MB to society > MC to society Does not increase output because MR to the firms is less than MC Price ($/unit of output) 3 D 12 24 Quantity (units/week)

Price ($/unit of output) Quantity (units/week) The Demand and Marginal Cost Curves for a Monopolist Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down Under Monopoly 6 Marginal cost 2 4 MR 8 Because MR<P, the monopoly produces less than the socially optimal amount The deadweight loss of the monopoy to society = (1/2)($2/unit)(4 units/wk) = $4/wk. Deadweight loss Price ($/unit of output) 3 D 12 24 Quantity (units/week) Slide 28

Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down Under Monopoly Profits are maximized where MR = MC. P > MR P > MC Deadweight loss Perfect Competition Profits are maximized where MR = MC. P = MR P = MC No deadweight loss

Why the Invisible Hand Breaks Down Under Monopoly Difficulties in Reducing the Deadweight Loss of Monopolies Enforcing antitrust laws Patents, copyrights, and innovation Natural monopolies

Price Discrimination The practice of charging different buyers different prices for essentially the same good or service Examples Senior citizens and student discounts on movie tickets Supersaver discounts on air travel Rebate coupons

Food For Thought Why do many movie theaters offer discount tickets to students?

Example: Carla Edit How many manuscripts should Carla edit?

Total and Marginal Revenue from Editing Reservation Price Total Revenue Marginal revenue Student ($ per paper) ($ per week) ($ per paper) A 40 40 B 38 76 C 36 108 D 34 136 E 32 160 F 30 180 G 28 196 H 26 208 40 36 32 28 24 20 16 12

Example: Single Price Monopoly How many manuscripts should Carla edit? Opportunity cost = $29 TR = P x Q, or for 4 papers, 4 x $34 = $136/wk MR is the difference in TR from adding another student If MR > MC: increase output

Example: Single Price Monopoly How many manuscripts should Carla edit? Carla edits 3 papers TC = 3 x $29 = $87 TR = $108 Economic profit = $108 - $87 = $21/wk

Example: Social Optimal How many manuscripts should Carla edit? O.C. of her time per editing= $29 Must charge the same price Reservation price > opportunity cost for student A to F Socially efficient number is 6 TR = 6 x $30 = $180 TC = 6 x $29 = $174 Economic profit = $180- $174 = $6

Example: Perfect Price Discrimination If Carla can do perfect price discriminate, how many papers should she edit? Assume Carla can charge each student the reservation price.

Example: Perfect Price Discrimination Reservation Student price A 40 B 38 C 36 D 34 E 32 F 30 G 28 H 26 Carla would edit A to F TR = $40 + $38… = $210 TC = 6 x $29 = $174 Economic Profit = $210 - $174 = $36/wk Economic Profit is $30 more

Perfect Price Discrimination Perfectly Discriminating Monopolist Charging each buyer exactly their reservation price Economic surplus is maximized Consumer surplus is zero Economic surplus = producer surplus

Limitation to Perfect Price Discrimination Seller will not know each buyer’s reservation price. Low price buyers could resell to other buyers at a higher price.

The Hurdle Method of Price Discrimination Profit-maximizing seller’s goal is to charge each buyer his/her reservation price. There are two problems to implementing this pricing strategy. Seller does not know the reservation prices Seller must separate high and low price buyers The hurdle method of price discrimination is used to solve these problems.

The Hurdle Method of Price Discrimination The practice of offering a discount to all buyers who overcome some obstacle. Example Offering a rebate to those who mail in a coupon

The Hurdle Method of Price Discrimination A Perfect Hurdle Separates buyers precisely according to their reservation prices What do you think? Is a perfect hurdle possible?

Example: Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Question How much should Carla charge for editing if she uses a perfect hurdle?

Example: Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Assume Carla offers a mail in rebate coupon Students with at least a $36 reservation price never use the coupon Students with a reservation price below $36 use the coupon Opportunity cost = $29 Discount coupon = $4

Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Reservation Price Total Revenue Marginal revenue Student ($ per paper) ($ per week) ($ per paper) List Price Submarket 40 36 32 A 40 40 B 38 76 C 36 108 D 34 34 E 32 64 F 30 90 G 28 112 H 26 130 Discount Price Submarket 34 30 26 22 18

Example: Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Solution TR = (3)(36) + (2)(32) = $172 MC = ($5)($29) = $145 Economic Profit = $27/wk

Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Is price discrimination a bad thing? In fact, the hurdle method raised economic surplus.

Calculating Economic Surplus Economic Surplus Under Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Calculating Economic Surplus Consumer Surplus Reservation Price Actual Price Consumer Surplus A $40 $36 $4 B $38 $36 $2 C $36 $36 $0 Both Single price & discount Without Discount $6 D $34 $22 $2 With Discount $8 Producer Surplus Single price = 3(36 - 29) = $21/wk Discount price = 3(36 - 29) = $21/wk 2(32 - 29) = $6/wk $27/wk

Calculating Economic Surplus Economic Surplus Under Price Discrimination with a Perfect Hurdle Calculating Economic Surplus Consumer Surplus Reservation Price Actual Price Consumer Surplus A $40 $36 $4 B $38 $36 $2 C $36 $36 $0 Both Single price & discount Without Discount $6 D $34 $22 $2 With Discount $8 Economic Surplus Single price = $6 + $21 = $27/wk Discount price = $8 + $27 = $35/wk Slide 51

Food For Thought Is Carla’s discount rebate completely efficient?

Examples of Price Discrimination Temporary Sales Book publishers and paperback books Automobile producers offer various models Commercial air carriers Movie producers

Single price monopolies are inefficient because P > MR. Summary Single price monopolies are inefficient because P > MR. The hurdle method of price discrimination reduces the inefficiency. The more finely the seller can discriminate, the smaller the efficiency loss. Hurdles are not perfect, therefore, there will be some efficiency loss.

End