DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Advertisements

DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
AAEC 2305 Fundamentals of Ag Economics Chapter 2 Economics of Demand.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
AAEC 2305 Fundamentals of Ag Economics Chapters 3 and 4—Part 1 Economics of Demand.
Chapter 2 Utility and Choice © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Indifference Curves and
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
© 2009, 2006 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning Demand Analysis Chapter 4.
Consumer Choice Theory. Overview Over the last several weeks, we have taken demand and supply curves as given. We now start examining where demand and.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY
Chapter Eight Slutsky Equation. Effects of a Price Change u What happens when a commodity’s price decreases? –Substitution effect: the commodity is relatively.
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
Part 2 Demand © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Individual Demand Curves
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Changes in Income An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel manner An increase in income will cause the budget constraint.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
Income and Substitution Effects
Elasticity and Consumer Surplus
Income and Substitution Effects
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization 21 C H A P T E R.
Individual and Market Demand
Individual Demand Curves
1 13. Expenditure minimization Econ 494 Spring 2013.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Utility Maximization and Choice
Chapter 4 Demand I have enough money to last me the rest of my life, unless I buy something. Jackie Mason.
Utility and Demand CHAPTER 7. 2 After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain what limits a household’s consumption choices Describe preferences.
Chapter 7 MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
Slutsky Equation.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
Indifference Analysis Appendix to Chapter 5. 2 Indifference Curves Indifference analysis is an alternative way of explaining consumer choice that does.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand
Individual and Market Demand Chapter 4 1. INDIVIDUAL DEMAND Price Changes Using the figures developed in the previous chapter, the impact of a change.
Objectives:  Use the utility-maximizing model to explain how consumers choose goods and services.  Use the concept of utility to explain how the law.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
SARBJEET KAUR Lecturer in Economics Indifference Curve Analysis.
1 Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
 Previously, we examined a consumer’s optimal choice under his budget constraint.  In this chapter, we will perform comparative static analysis of ordinary.
1 Sir Naseer Shahzada INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Utility- is the satisfaction you receive from consuming a good or service Total utility is the number of units of utility that a consumer gains from consuming.
1 Chapter 6 Consumer Choice Theory ©2002 South-Western College Publishing Key Concepts Summary Practice Quiz Internet Exercises Internet Exercises.
Demand: It is the quantity of a good or service that customers are willing and able to purchase during a specified period under a given set of economic.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
Chapter 8 SLUTSKY EQUATION. Substitution Effect and Income Effect x1x1 x2x2 m/p 2 m’/p 2 X Y Z Substitution Effect Income Effect Shift Pivot.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
Lecture by: Jacinto F. Fabiosa Fall 2005 Demand. 2 A household’s quantity demanded of a good –Specific amount household would choose to buy over some.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Consumer Welfare 1. 2 One way to evaluate the welfare cost of a price increase (from p x 0 to p x 1 ) would be to compare the expenditures required to.
MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY
Demand Relationships among Goods
Demand Relationships among Goods
Demand Relationships among Goods
Presentation transcript:

DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS Chapter 6 DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS

The Two-Good Case The types of relationships that can occur when there are only two goods are limited But this case can be illustrated with two-dimensional graphs

Gross Complements Quantity of y x1 x0 y1 y0 U1 U0 When the price of y falls, the substitution effect may be so small that the consumer purchases more x and more y In this case, we call x and y gross complements x/py < 0 Quantity of x

Gross Substitutes Quantity of y x1 x0 y1 y0 U0 When the price of y falls, the substitution effect may be so large that the consumer purchases less x and more y U1 In this case, we call x and y gross substitutes x/py > 0 Quantity of x

A Mathematical Treatment The change in x caused by changes in py can be shown by a Slutsky-type equation substitution effect (+) income effect (-) if x is normal combined effect (ambiguous)

Substitutes and Complements For the case of many goods, we can generalize the Slutsky analysis for any i or j this implies that the change in the price of any good induces income and substitution effects that may change the quantity of every good demanded

Substitutes and Complements Two goods are substitutes if one good may replace the other in use examples: tea & coffee, butter & margarine Two goods are complements if they are used together examples: coffee & cream, fish & chips

Gross Substitutes and Complements The concepts of gross substitutes and complements include both substitution and income effects two goods are gross substitutes if xi /pj > 0 two goods are gross complements if xi /pj < 0

Asymmetry of the Gross Definitions One undesirable characteristic of the gross definitions of substitutes and complements is that they are not symmetric It is possible for x1 to be a substitute for x2 and at the same time for x2 to be a complement of x1

Asymmetry of the Gross Definitions Suppose that the utility function for two goods is given by U(x,y) = ln x + y Setting up the Lagrangian L = ln x + y + (I – pxx – pyy)

Asymmetry of the Gross Definitions gives us the following first-order conditions: L/x = 1/x - px = 0 L/y = 1 - py = 0 L/ = I - pxx - pyy = 0 Manipulating the first two equations, we get pxx = py

Asymmetry of the Gross Definitions Inserting this into the budget constraint, we can find the Marshallian demand for y pyy = I – py an increase in py causes a decline in spending on y since px and I are unchanged, spending on x must rise ( x and y are gross substitutes) but spending on y is independent of px ( x and y are independent of one another)

Net Substitutes and Complements The concepts of net substitutes and complements focuses solely on substitution effects two goods are net substitutes if two goods are net complements if

Net Substitutes and Complements This definition looks only at the shape of the indifference curve This definition is unambiguous because the definitions are perfectly symmetric

Gross Complements Even though x and y are gross complements, they are net substitutes Quantity of y Since MRS is diminishing, the own-price substitution effect must be negative so the cross-price substitution effect must be positive y1 y0 U1 U0 x0 x1 Quantity of x

Substitutability with Many Goods Once the utility-maximizing model is extended to may goods, a wide variety of demand patterns become possible According to Hicks’ second law of demand, “most” goods must be substitutes

Substitutability with Many Goods To prove this, we can start with the compensated demand function xc(p1,…pn,V) Applying Euler’s theorem yields

Substitutability with Many Goods In elasticity terms, we get Since the negativity of the substitution effect implies that eiic  0, it must be the case that

Composite Commodities In the most general case, an individual who consumes n goods will have demand functions that reflect n(n+1)/2 different substitution effects It is often convenient to group goods into larger aggregates examples: food, clothing, “all other goods”

Composite Commodity Theorem Suppose that consumers choose among n goods The demand for x1 will depend on the prices of the other n-1 commodities If all of these prices move together, it may make sense to lump them into a single composite commodity (y)

Composite Commodity Theorem Let p20…pn0 represent the initial prices of these other commodities assume that they all vary together (so that the relative prices of x2…xn do not change) Define the composite commodity y to be total expenditures on x2…xn at the initial prices y = p20x2 + p30x3 +…+ pn0xn

Composite Commodity Theorem The individual’s budget constraint is I = p1x1 + p20x2 +…+ pn0xn = p1x1 + y If we assume that all of the prices p20…pn0 change by the same factor (t > 0) then the budget constraint becomes I = p1x1 + tp20x2 +…+ tpn0xn = p1x1 + ty changes in p1 or t induce substitution effects

Composite Commodity Theorem As long as p20…pn0 move together, we can confine our examination of demand to choices between buying x1 and “everything else” The theorem makes no prediction about how choices of x2…xn behave only focuses on total spending on x2…xn

Composite Commodity A composite commodity is a group of goods for which all prices move together These goods can be treated as a single commodity the individual behaves as if he is choosing between other goods and spending on this entire composite group

Example: Composite Commodity Suppose that an individual receives utility from three goods: food (x) housing services (y), measured in hundreds of square feet household operations (z), measured by electricity use Assume a CES utility function

Example: Composite Commodity The Lagrangian technique can be used to derive demand functions

Example: Composite Commodity If initially I = 100, px = 1, py = 4, and pz = 1, then x* = 25, y* = 12.5, z* = 25 $25 is spent on food and $75 is spent on housing-related needs

Example: Composite Commodity If we assume that the prices of housing services (py) and electricity (pz) move together, we can use their initial prices to define the “composite commodity” housing (h) h = 4y + 1z The initial quantity of housing is the total spent on housing (75)

Example: Composite Commodity Now x can be shown as a function of I, px, and ph If I = 100, px = 1, py = 4, and ph = 1, then x* = 25 and spending on housing (h*) = 75

Example: Composite Commodity If py rises to 16 and pz rises to 4 (with px remaining at 1), ph would also rise to 4 The demand for x would fall to Housing purchases would be given by

Example: Composite Commodity Since ph = 4, h* = 150/7 If I = 100, px = 1, py = 16, and pz = 4, the individual demand functions show that x* = 100/7, y* = 100/28, z* = 100/14 This means that the amount of h that is consumed can also be computed as h* = 4y* + 1z* = 150/7