Part 4 Chapter 11 Yulin Department of Finance, Xiamen University.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chp.4 Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty
Advertisements

Hal Varian Intermediate Microeconomics Chapter Thirteen
Introduction to Portfolio Selection and Capital Market Theory: Static Analysis
Appendix 27A: An Alternative Method to Derive The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model (Related to 27.5) By Cheng Few Lee Joseph Finnerty John Lee Alice.
Risk Aversion and Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
COMM 472: Quantitative Analysis of Financial Decisions
The securities market economy -- theory Abstracting again to the two- period analysis - - but to different states of payoff.
INVESTMENTS: Analysis and Management Second Canadian Edition INVESTMENTS: Analysis and Management Second Canadian Edition W. Sean Cleary Charles P. Jones.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull The Black-Scholes- Merton Model Chapter 13.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Ch.7 The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Another View About Risk
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN INVESTMENTS.
Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing What effect does psychological bias (irrationality) have on asset demands and asset prices?
An Introduction to Asset Pricing Models
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
L11: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing 1 Lecture 11: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing The following topics will be covered: Pareto Efficient Risk Allocation.
5.2Risk-Neutral Measure Part 2 報告者:陳政岳 Stock Under the Risk-Neutral Measure is a Brownian motion on a probability space, and is a filtration for.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
Chapter 13 Stochastic Optimal Control The state of the system is represented by a controlled stochastic process. Section 13.2 formulates a stochastic optimal.
Lecture 3: Arrow-Debreu Economy
Chapter 3 Common Stock: Return, Growth, and Risk By Cheng Few Lee Joseph Finnerty John Lee Alice C Lee Donald Wort.
1 Finance School of Management Chapter 13: The Capital Asset Pricing Model Objective The Theory of the CAPM Use of CAPM in benchmarking Using CAPM to determine.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
11.1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th Edition © 1999 by John C. Hull The Black-Scholes Model Chapter 11.
1 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model MGT 821/ECON 873 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model.
Cost of Capital MF 807 Corporate Finance Professor Thomas Chemmanur.
VALUATION OF BONDS AND SHARES CHAPTER 3. LEARNING OBJECTIVES  Explain the fundamental characteristics of ordinary shares, preference shares and bonds.
The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black- Scholes Chapter 12.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
Corporate Banking and Investment Risk tolerance and optimal portfolio choice Marek Musiela, BNP Paribas, London.
Chapter 3 Discrete Time and State Models. Discount Functions.
Lecture 10 The Capital Asset Pricing Model Expectation, variance, standard error (deviation), covariance, and correlation of returns may be based on.
© Markus Rudolf Page 1 Intertemporal Surplus Management BFS meeting Internet-Page: Intertemporal Surplus Management 1. Basics.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
5.4 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 報告者:何俊儒.
L8: Consumption Based CAPM1 Lecture 8: Basics of Consumption-based Models The following topics will be covered: Overview of Consumption-based Models –Basic.
Online Financial Intermediation. Types of Intermediaries Brokers –Match buyers and sellers Retailers –Buy products from sellers and resell to buyers Transformers.
Black Scholes Option Pricing Model Finance (Derivative Securities) 312 Tuesday, 10 October 2006 Readings: Chapter 12.
Capital Asset Pricing Model CAPM I: The Theory. Introduction Asset Pricing – how assets are priced? Equilibrium concept Portfolio Theory – ANY individual.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model Yuna Rhee Seyong Park Robert C. Merton (1971) [Journal.
Computational Finance 1/34 Panos Parpas Asset Pricing Models 381 Computational Finance Imperial College London.
The Goods Market Lecture 11 – academic year 2013/14 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini.
Chp.5 Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous Time Model Hai Lin Department of Finance, Xiamen University.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 6.
Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 7th Ed, Ch 13, Copyright © John C. Hull 2010 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter.
Financial Analysis, Planning and Forecasting Theory and Application By Alice C. Lee San Francisco State University John C. Lee J.P. Morgan Chase Cheng.
© Prentice Hall, Corporate Financial Management 3e Emery Finnerty Stowe Derivatives Applications.
Investment Performance Measurement, Risk Tolerance and Optimal Portfolio Choice Marek Musiela, BNP Paribas, London.
Risk and Return: Portfolio Theory and Assets Pricing Models
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th International Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter B-S-M model is used to determine the option price of any underlying stock. They believed that stock follow.
The Capital Asset Pricing Model Lecture XII. .Literature u Most of today’s materials comes from Eugene F. Fama and Merton H. Miller The Theory of Finance.
Framework. Notation r=vector of excess returns –Bold signifies vectors and matrices. We denote individual stock excess returns as r n. –Excess above risk.
Summary of Previous Lecture In previous lecture, we revised chapter 4 about the “Valuation of the Long Term Securities” and covered the following topics.
MTH 105. FINANCIAL MARKETS What is a Financial market: - A financial market is a mechanism that allows people to trade financial security. Transactions.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model 1. The Stock Price Assumption Consider a stock whose price is S In a short period of time of length  t, the.
L6: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing1 Lecture 6: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing The following topics will be covered: Pareto Efficient Risk Allocation –Defining.
Security Markets V Miloslav S Vošvrda Theory of Capital Markets.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Capital Market Theory: An Overview
Risk and Return.
Theory of Capital Markets
Theory of Capital Markets
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 12: On the Pricing of Corporate Debt
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chp.9 Option Pricing When Underlying Stock Returns are Discontinuous
Presentation transcript:

Part 4 Chapter 11 Yulin Department of Finance, Xiamen University

Main line: 1 A partial-equilibrium one-period model 2 A general intertemporal equilibrium model of the asset market, includes three models(model 1 is based on a constant interest rate assumption, model 2 is a no-riskless-asset case, model 3 is the general model).

Ⅰ A partial-equilibrium one- period model We follows the warrant pricing approach used in Chapter 7, that is, investors choose among three assets: the warrant, the stock of the firm and a riskless asset to form optimal portfolios which maximize their expected utility.

Consider an economy made up of only one firm with current value, and there exists a “ representative man ” acts so as to maximize the expected utility of wealth at the end of a period of length, that is, …… ① Define a random variable Z by and assume its probability distribution is known at present, more importantly,

is independent of the particular structure of the firm, this is consistent with the MM(Modigliani-Miller) theorem. Define as the current value of the i th type of security issued by the firm. The different types of securities are distinguishable by their terminal value. For a debt issue(i=1), … ②

Because each of the securities appears separately in the market, so: and Define, so we can rewrite ① as a maximization under constraint: ① … ③

The corresponding first-order conditions are: This can be rewritten in terms of util- prob distributions Q as: … ④

Where and is a new multiplier related to. dQ is independent of the functions by the assumption that the value of the firm is independent of its capital structure, so ④ is a set of integral equations linear in the, and we can rewrite ④ as

… * Suppose the firm issues just one type of security--equity, then Substituting in ④, we have

From ④, we can see that the expected return on all securities in util-prob space must be equated. If U was linear, then dQ=dP and ④ would imply the result for the risk-neutral case. Hence, the util-prob distribution is the distribution of returns adjusted for risk.

Some examples Example 1: Firm issues two types of securities, debt and equity with current value and respectively. From ② and ④, we have ⑤ : ② ④ ⑤

Suppose or for then as. In the limit, the debt becomes riskless, so will be replaced by r. Another useful form of ⑤ is Since in equilibrium

So,. This is identical to the warrant pricing equation derived in Chapter 7. This equation can also be derived directly from the terminal value of equity in the same way as debt.

Example 2: Firm ’ s capital structure made up from three types of securities: debt, equity(N shares outstanding with current price per share of S, i.e. ), warrants (exercise price is ). Assume there are n warrants outstanding with current market value per warrant of W,

i.e.. Because the warrant is a junior security to the debt, the current value of the debt will be the same as in the first example. The current value of the equity will be the first example … ⑥

Where. Rewrite ⑥ as … ⑦

In equilibrium,. So from ⑦ we have ⑧ If we define normalized price of the firm as

And define the normalized price of a warrant as, then ⑧ can be rewritten as which is of the same form as equation (7.24).

Example 3: Firm ’ s capital structure contains two securities:convertible bonds with a total terminal claim on the firm of either B dollars or alternatively the bonds can be exchanged for a total of n shares of equity; and N shares of equity with current price per share of S dollars.

So,, and Where is determined to be.

By inspection of this equation, we have the well-known result that the value of a convertible bond is equal to its value as a straight bond plus a warrant with exercise price.

Example 4: A “ dual ” fund: it issues two types of securities to finance its assets: namely, capital shares(equity) which are entitled to all the accumulated capital gains(in excess of the fixed terminal payment); and income-shares(a type of bond) which are entitled to all the ordinary

income in addition to a fixed terminal payment. Let be the instantaneous fixed proportion of total asset value earned as ordinary income, V be the current asset value of the fund and Z the total return on the fund.

Let be the current value of the income shares with terminal claim on the fund of B dollars plus all interest and dividends earned, be the current value of the capital shares. So, from definition, we have

And Where. The current value of the capital shares can be less than the current net asset value of the capital shares, defined to

be V-B, because If, that is, then,.

Ⅱ A general intertemporal equilibrium model Consider an economy with K consumers – investors and n firms with current value.Each consumer acts so as to Define, where is the number of shares and is the price per share at time t.

Assume that expectations about the dynamics of the prices per share in the futures are the same for all investors and can be described by the stochastic differential equation:

Further assume that one of the n assets (the nth one) is an instantaneously riskless asset with instantaneous return : For simplicity, we assume that and are functions only of.

From, divide both side by and substitute for,then The accumulation equation for the kth investor can be written as … ⑨ ⑨

Where is his wage income and is the fraction of his wealth invested in the ith security. So, his demand for the ith security can be written as Where is the number of shares of the ith security demanded by investor k.

Substituting for, we can rewrite ⑨ as From the budget constraint, and from ⑨, we have i.e. the net value of shares purchased must equal the value of savings from wage income.

According to Chapter 4 and 5, the necessary optimality conditions for an individual who acts to maximize his expected utility are (10) subject to.

From (10), we can derive m+1 first-order conditions (11) (12) Equation (12) can be solved explicitly for the demand functions for each risky security as

where the are the elements of the inverse of the instantaneous variance- covariance matrix of returns, and. Applying the Implicit Function Theorem to (11), we have

The aggregate demands are (13) If it is assumed that the asset market is always in equilibrium, then,where M is the total value of all assets. So, from ⑨ ⑨ (14)

Let be the price per “ share ” of the market portfolio and N be the number of “ shares ”, i.e.. Then, N and are defined by

From and, then And from (13), we get (15) Define.Divide equation (14) by M and substitute for

We can rewrite (15) as (16) And from this we can determine

From (13), we can solve for the yields on individual risky assets in matrix- vector form:(13) (17) Since in equilibrium,, it can be rewritten in scalar form as (18)

Multiplying both side by and summing from 1 to m, we have (19) Hence, from (18) and (19), if we know the equilibrium prices, then the equilibrium expected yields of the risky assets and the market portfolio can be determined. The equilibrium interest rate can be determined from (11).

Model 1: A constant interest rate assumption With a constant interest rate, the ratios of an investor ’ s demands for risk assets are the same for all investors. Hence, the “ mutual-fund ” or separation theorem holds, and all optimal portfolios can be represented as a linear combination of any two distinct efficient portfolios(we can choose them to be the market portfolio and the riskless asset).

By combining (18) and (19) we have (20) With a slightly different interpretation of the variables, (20) is the equation for the Security Market Line of CAPM. If it is assumed that the are constant over time, then from (16), is log- normally distributed.

We can integrate the stochastic process for to get conditional on where is a normal variate with zero mean and variance. Similarly, we can integrate (16) to get

where is a normal variate with zero mean and variance. Define the variables

Then consider the ordinary least-squares regression, if Model 1 is the true specification, then the following must hold: ; ; is a normal variate with zero mean and a covariance with the market return of zero.

Reconsider the first example where firm ’ s capital structure consists of two securities: equity and debt, and it is assumed that the firm is enjoined from the issue or purchase of securities prior to the redemption date of the debt namely, So, (21)

Let be the current value of the debt with years until maturity and with redemption value at that time of B. Let be the current value of equity and the dynamics of the return on equity can be written as (22)

(20) Like every security in the economy, the equity of the firm must satisfy (20) in equilibrium, hence, (23) By Ito ’ s lemma, substitute dV from (21), we get: (24)

Comparing (24) with (22), it must be that (25) (26) And also, in equilibrium, (27) Substituting for and from (23) and (27), we have the Fundamental Partial

Differential Equation of Security Pricing (28) subject to the boundary condition The solution is (29) Z is a log-normally distributed random variable with mean and variance of, and is the log-normal density function.

(28) is the Fundamental Partial Differential Equation of Asset Pricing because all the securities in the firm ’ s capital structure must satisfy it. And each securities are distinguished by their terminal claims. Equation (29) can be rewritten in general form as (30)

Although (30) is a kind of discounted expected value formula, one should not infer that the expected return on F is r. From (23),(26) and (27), the expected return on F can be written as

(28) was derived by Black and Scholes (1973) under the assumption of market equilibrium when pricing option contracts, but it actually holds without this assumption. Consider a two-asset portfolio which contains the firm as one security and any one of the security in the firm ’ s capital structure as the other.

Let P be the price per unit of this portfolio, the fraction of the total portfolio ’ s value invested in the firm and the fraction in the particular security chosen from the firm ’ s capital structure. So,

Suppose is chosen such that Then the portfolio will be perfectly hedged and the instantaneous return on the portfolio will be certain(equal to r),that is,. So. Then, as was done previously, we can arrived at (28). Nowhere was the market equilibrium assumption needed!

Remarks: Although the value of the firm follows a simple dynamic process with constant parameters, the individual component securities follow more complex processes with changing expected returns and variances. Thus, in empirical examinations using a regression, if one were to use equity instead of firm values, systematic biases would be introduced.

Model 2: The “ no riskless asset ” case If there exists uncertain inflation and there are no future markets in consumption goods or other guaranteed “ purchasing power ” securities available, there will be no perfect hedge against future price changes, i.e. no riskless asset exists.

Follow the same procedure as in section 11.4, we can derive analogous equilibrium conditions, namely, (31) (32) The nth security must satisfy (31) in equilibrium (33)

Solve and G in (32),(33) and substitute them into (31), we have (34) In a similar fashion to the analysis in Model 1, we get the Fundamental Partial Differential Equation for Security Pricing,where

If security n is a zero-beta security, i.e.,then,and (34) can be rewritten as where.

Model 3: The general model In this model, the interest rate varies stochastically over time. In section 11.4, we have (35) (36)

So, (37) Solve (36) and (37) for and, and substitute them into (35), we have (38) where and

Theorem 11.1(Three “ Fund ” Theorem) Given n assets satisfying the conditions of the model in section 11.4, there exist three portfolios ( “ mutual funds ” ) constructed from these n assets such that all risk-averse individuals, who behave to maximize their expected utilities, will be indifferent from these three funds.Further, a possible choice for the three funds is the market portfolio, the riskless asset, and a portfolio which is (instantaneously)perfectly correlated with changes in the interest rate.

Since in this model, the interest rate varies stochastically, we can determine the term structure from this model, and nowhere in the model is it necessary to introduce concepts such as liquidity, transactions costs,time horizon or habit to explain the existence of a term structure.

Suppose there exists a security(mth security) is perfectly correlated with changes in the interest rate, and its dynamics are described by (39) and from, we have

Let be the price of a discounted loan which pays a dollar at time in the future when the current interest rate is r. Then the dynamics of P can be written as. And also we have

(38) Set in (38) and substitute, we have (40) By Ito ’ s lemma, and must satisfy (41)

So, given, (41) can be solved to determine and hence the term structure of interest rate. Suppose the Expectations Hypothesis holds, then for all and the term structure is completely determined by (42) subject to.

(38) From (40), it must be that in equilibrium,and the equilibrium condition (38) simplifies to

And further if we assume f and g are constants, we have the explicit solution for (42): Note that as,which is not at all reasonable.

Just in the similar way as Model 1 and Model 2,we can derive the Fundamental Equation of Security Pricing as subject to an appropriate boundary condition.

Remark 1: the model does not allow for nonhomogeneous expectations, non-serially independent preferences, or transactions costs. Remark 2:the fundamental assumption in this model is continuous-time assumption.If the model were formulated in discrete time, then the results derived in this chapter no longer hold.

The end Thanks!