The CFI Microsoft Judgment: Abuse 1 - Interoperability Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading NB The views expressed here are my own,

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Competitive Aspects of PSI Re-use Bruxelles, January 24 th, 2012.
Advertisements

Policy Recommendation on Competitive Issues of PSI Re-use First draft … and beyond … Warsaw, October 20 th, 2011.
The EU Microsoft Decision Aryeh Friedman AT&T Corp.
THE PATH LAID BY TRINKO: EU Microsoft (interoperability issue) in light of Trinko and IMS Eleanor M. Fox New York University School of Law Global Competition.
Competition enforcement and software – some thoughts following Microsoft v. Commission Brno competition law conference 25 October 2007 Becket McGrath Partner,
Competition Policy and Consumer Protection Dr. Patrick Krauskopf Swiss Competition Commission (COMCO) National Training Workshop on Competition Policy.
IP rights and competition law: Friends or foes? Etienne Wéry Attorney at the bars of Paris and Brussels Lecturer at Robert Schuman University (Strasbourg)
A TALE OF TWO EUROPEAN CASES: IBM and Microsoft John Vickers Oxford University Dutch Association for Competition Law Amsterdam, 15 May 2008 [Based on paper.
Consumers and Competition: making policies that work together Michael Jenkin Consumer Affairs, Industry Canada Louise Sylvan ACCC.
Session 8: Remedies in Competition Policy Mergers and Unilateral Conduct Fifth Annual African Consumer Protection Dialogue Conference Livingstone, Zambia.
Competition Policy in Two-Sided Markets - Some brief remarks Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading LEAR Conference 7th June 2007 NB.
Economics RBB LONDONADRIAN MAJUMDAR Foreclosure, Rollback Rebates & Tomra 1 May 2007
Price-cost Tests v. Raising Rivals’ Costs for Loyalty Programs and its Implication for the Taking of Advantage of Market Power Provisions 2 nd ATE Symposium.
Dominance – the lost child? Do effects-based rules mean the end of dominance analysis? BICCL Reform of Article February 2006 Thomas Eilmansberger,
1 REFORM OF ARTICLE 82 EC BIICL, 24 February 2006 Treatment of Rebates Johanne Peyre.
Regulating a Monopolist Monopolist choose output q m,whereas the efficient output is q w. Regulation will be needed to avoid the former result. However,
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
The EU Microsoft case: tying abuse Per Hellström DG Competition, European Commission (speaking in a personal capacity - the views expressed are not necessarily.
1 Regulations on Abuse of Market Dominance in Korea (Analysis & Case Study) Jaeho Moon Korea Fair Trade Commission.
Sherman Act Section 2 Committee Hot Topics in Monopolization Law “Section 2 in the Antitrust Division” J. Bruce McDonald March 31, 2005 UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT.
6 th Annual Conference Moscow, 30 May Unilateral Conduct Working Group Case Study in the Assessment of Dominance British Airways plc v. Commission.
London 22 Nov 2005 Modernization of Article 82 Lars-Hendrik Röller * Chief Competition Economist European Commission CLA and BIICL Conference on Article.
TILEC – T ILBURG L AW AND E CONOMICS C ENTER Innovation: a challenge for law Pierre Larouche Professor of Competition Law Colloquium.
Where now for Article 82? Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading BIICL Transatlantic Dialogue 15 May 2008 (The views expressed here are.
Monopoly. Monopoly A monopoly is one business firm that produces the entire market supply of a particular good or service. A monopoly is one business.
The EU Microsoft case: refusal to supply Nicholas Banasevic DG Competition, European Commission (speaking in a personal capacity - the views expressed.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
Introductory course on Competition and Regulation Pál Belényesi University of Verona October 2006.
MERGERS Clayton 7 as amended by the Celler-Kefauver Act:
IMPACT ESTIMATION PROJECT What do policy-makers need from behavioural economists? Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist UK Office of Fair Trading DGSanco.
Enforcing Competition on the Internet Howard Shelanski Georgetown University February 13, 2012.
마스터 제목 스타일 편집 마스터 텍스트 스타일을 편집합니다 둘째 수준 셋째 수준 넷째 수준 다섯째 수준 In Ok Son Korea Fair Trade Commission Abuse of dominance in hi-tech markets and network.
From « Guidelines on the applicability of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to horizontal cooperation Agreements » The purpose of these guidelines is to provide.
Conglomerate Merger Control After Tetra Laval Sven B. Völcker 29 April 2005.
1 FRAND COMMITMENTS AND EU COMPETITION LAW Thomas Kramler European Commission, DG Competition (The views expressed are not necessarily those of the European.
How to assess vertical mergers cast your vote! Miguel de la Mano* Member of the Chief Economist Team DG COMP, European Commission *The views expressed.
1 Remedies under Article 82 EC Per Hellström DG Competition, European Commission (speaking in a personal capacity - the views expressed are not necessarily.
Competition Policy and Law Presentation to Study Tour for Russian Member Universities of the Virtual Institute Network 26 March 2009.
MARKET STRUCTURE Perfect competition MonopolyOligopoly.
CAPACITY BUILDING – INDIA; ABUSE OF DOMINANCE Eleanor M. Fox Professor, New York University School of Law CUTS-CIRC New Delhi 18 Jan 06.
ACE 2007 Potentially excessive prices and switching costs: banking cases from Hungary (OTP Bank) Bruno Jullien.
Commission Vs. Microsoft: "Rights", "Wrongs" and Priorities for Economic Analysis Prof. Yannis Katsoulacos, Athens University of Economics and Business,
Exclusionary Conduct in the Context of Standard Setting William E. Cohen Deputy General Counsel for Policy Studies U.S. Federal Trade Commission Views.
1 Economic Analysis in Competition Law – A Lawyer’s Perspective A. Douglas Melamed March 23, 2009.
Unit (7) Why businesses make decisions? The decision that they make might include. - what to produces, where to locate the premises, what method of production.
Post Danmark II in context
The dominance concept: new wine in old bottles Miguel de la Mano * Member of the Chief Economist’s Office DG COMP, European Commission FTC/DOJ Hearings.
The Free Enterprise Chapter Analyze the Free Enterprise.
ABA China Inside and Out September , Beijing The interface between competition law and intellectual property Nicholas Banasevic, DG Competition,
SMP and dominance Pál Belényesi Verona 29 November November 2006.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
EU Discussion Paper on Exclusionary Abuses Michael Albers European Commission DG Competition 54th Antitrust Law Spring Meeting Washington DC, 30 March.
1 The role of Economics in European Competition Enforcement and Policy Damien Neven, Chief Economist * DG COMP, European Commission 5 th International.
European competition policy. Role of competition policy Promote economic efficiency To control intensity of competition within economy Some areas it is.
COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct.
Exercise of IP rights as an abusive behaviour under EU antitrust law Christian Vollrath European Commission DG Competition 1.
Standards and competition policy EU-China Workshop on Application of Anti-monopoly Law in Intellectual Property Area Changsha, 11. – 12. March 2010 Peter.
Identification of Abuse of dominant market position involving IPR Wang Xianlin, KoGoan Law School of Shanghai Jiaotong University Dalian,June 11,2010.
The Case against Microsoft. © 2004 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved12-2.
Pros& cons Dr. Musab Barakat Ahmed Ali PhD.;FCCA;FCMI Chartered Certified Accountant Practicing firm Barakat&co Senior partner & CEO Consultant National.
Government intervention and competition policy 3.
Dialogue on Competition Policy and Intellectual Property *
European Union Law Week 10.
EU Competition Rules for Technology Transfer Agreements
Ian Bracy Brian Hendel David Jones
Dr Pınar Akman Associate Professor School of Law, University of Leeds
Competition Policy and Consumer Protection
Standards and competition law Michael Adam DG Competition, European Commission (speaking in a personal capacity - the views expressed are not necessarily.
Presentation transcript:

The CFI Microsoft Judgment: Abuse 1 - Interoperability Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading NB The views expressed here are my own, and not necessarily those of the OFT

Refusal to Supply by Microsoft: The basic economic story I ● Microsoft Windows has a ‘quasi-monopolistic’ position in the supply of PC operating systems ● For non-Microsoft servers to work effectively with client PCs (and servers) running on Windows, interoperability with the ‘Windows domain architecture’ is required ● This is not being provided (and previously was) ● As a result, Microsoft has quickly gained a dominant position on the server market, and its position continues to strengthen

● Microsoft’s share of work group server OS market had experienced rapid and significant growth:  25% in 1996 to  61% in 2002 (by turnover) ● Substantial and continuing decline in market shares of Sun, Novell and Linux ● Competitors not eliminated but non-Windows servers restricted to certain tasks such as print servers or based on legacy installations Facts of the case: The foreclosing effects of the refusal to supply

Refusal to Supply by Microsoft: The basic economic story II ● Microsoft has an incentive to foreclose the server market:  A key exception to the Chicago School ‘one monopoly profit’ argument relates to the situation where, by foreclosing market B, the monopolist can prolong its own monopoly over market A.  Here, by gaining and strengthening a dominant position in servers, Microsoft can (1) reinforce barriers to entry into client PC operating systems, and (2) prevent (or control) any paradigm shift towards server-centric IT solutions

Refusal to Supply: Pro-competitive benefits ● It is typically pro-competitive for firms to be able to choose their trading partners (or deny supply):  The threat to refuse to supply plays a key role in competitive commercial negotiations  Exclusive relationships can be crucial for incentivising relationship-specific investments  Firms compete partly on the basis of the strength of their trading relationships (or ability to self-supply)  In the case of IPRs: IPRs are specifically designed to provide ex post exclusivity following innovation, in order ex ante to incentivise such innovation

Suggests a high hurdle for Refusal to Supply IPRs cases ● Only intervene if:  Likely effect on competition is substantial  There is a clear story on the incentive for abuse  The abuse harms dynamic competition, and therefore innovation, not just static competition  The intervention (or threat of such interventions in the future) does not harm innovation indirectly (by altering innovation incentives) by more than the abuse harms it directly.

Refusal to Supply IPRs: Economic enforcement policy I ● Does Firm X have the ability to foreclose?  Is the refused product ‘necessary’ for others firms to compete effectively in market B? ● Has it foreclosed all effective competition?  Have all competitors been refused supply? ● Does the firm have the incentive to foreclose?  Does Firm X also compete in market B?  Does the ‘one monopoly profit’ argument hold? ● On balance, is innovation likely to be harmed?

Refusal to Supply IPRs: Economic enforcement policy II ● On balance, is innovation likely to be harmed?  Is there likely harm to dynamic competition from the refusal to supply in this case?  How high is the risk to ex ante innovation from (the threat of) interventions such as this?  Does the former effect exceed the latter?

Refusal to Supply by Microsoft: The Commission’s Approach ● “The case-law of the European Courts suggests that the Commission must analyse the entirety of the circumstances surrounding a specific instance of a refusal to supply and must take its decision based on the results of such a comprehensive examination” ● “There is no persuasiveness to an approach that would advocate the existence of an exhaustive checklist of “exceptional circumstances”… [for finding abuse]”

Refusal to Supply by Microsoft: The Commission’s Key Findings Ability to foreclose ● Interoperability necessary for server OS vendors to be effective competitors. There are no substitutes. Substantial Foreclosure Effect ● All competitors refused interoperability ● Microsoft’s share in server market rising fast and indeed now dominant Incentive to foreclose ● The ‘one monopoly profit’ argument fails on the facts Harm to innovation ● Risk of harm to innovation from abuse that outweighs potential harm to innovation incentives from intervention

● Not made explicit, but question should be whether supply of the relevant info would have harmed Microsoft’s innovation incentives, had it known ex ante the supply would be required ● Commission found no significant negative effect:  Supply of relevant info would not enable ‘cloning’ of Microsoft’s servers  Such disclosure is normal practice in this industry  Other disclosures have been required, and these do not seem to have harmed innovation No significant harm to innovation incentives from intervention

Refusal to supply by Microsoft: The CFI’s Approach ● Treated as IPR (although not clear), as did EC ● Case law says refusal to supply will be abusive only in exceptional circumstances, including:  Indispensability  Exclusion of any effective competition  Prevents appearance of a new product  No objective justification ● The Court carried out only a ‘limited review’ of the Commission’s ‘complex economic assessments’

Ability to foreclose ● Interoperability necessary for server OS vendors to be effective competitors. There are no substitutes. Substantial Foreclosure Effect ● All competitors refused interoperability ● Microsoft’s share in server market rising fast and indeed now dominant Incentive to foreclose ● The ‘one monopoly profit’ argument fails on the facts Harm to innovation ● Risk of harm to innovation from abuse that outweighs potential harm to innovation incentives from intervention Refusal to Supply: The Commission’s Key Findings Indispensability Exclusion of any effective competition Prevents appearance of new product AND No objective justification No objective justification

A reaction to the CFI judgment “the standard applied to unilateral conduct by the CFI, rather than helping consumers, may have the unfortunate consequence of harming consumers by chilling innovation and discouraging competition.” Thomas Barnett US DOJ

● The CFI test for effect is ‘risk of elimination of any effective competition’, but in market B ● What if the real motivation for Firm X’s refusal is to protect its monopoly position in market A ● Now, what if Firm X did supply some competitors in market B – enough for effective competition – but none who might pose a threat in market A? ● Clear incentive and effect, but how would this case be run legally? No rounded story on effect

● The Commission appears to recognise the need for balancing up positive and negative effects ● Microsoft challenges this ‘new evaluation test’ as legally defective, vague and impossible to apply ● CFI opines: Balancing is not appropriate but is a misreading of the Commission’s Decision  Rather, Commission finds no significant negative effect on Microsoft’s incentives to innovate from intervention that would offset the harm to technical development from the refusal to supply No role for balancing in assessing harm to innovation

● The Commission examined carefully Microsoft’s ‘one monopoly profit’ argument for why it had no incentive to foreclose ● No CFI discussion of this. Why?  Because fully dispensed at Commission stage?  Or because irrelevant under EC case law? ● Sadly, probably the latter ● But should be one of first things to think about! No analysis of incentive to foreclose

● Commission tell a story of anti-competitive incentive and effect, and why refusal is not justified by innovation incentives ● CFI follows a checklist approach (and does not reopen any ‘complex economic assessment’) ● Pro: The CFI needed to do this to avoid appeal, so shouldn’t read as negative about the ‘more economic approach’ ● Con: Possibly dangerous. Rough congruence here, but not necessarily In summary

● Microsoft required to provide interoperability information to Windows domain architecture, i.e:  Provide interoperability information to allow non- Microsoft servers to interact with Microsoft client PCs  Provide interface information to allow non-Microsoft servers to interact with Microsoft servers ● Why the latter?  Would this remedy have been imposed if Microsoft had not been dominant in server market?  Yes, due to the technical nature of this product. But otherwise? Does the remedy reflect the abuse?