SID, SAV, and Efficient Use Chapter 15 © Allen C. Goodman, 2013.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Consumer Choice and Elasticity
Advertisements

Labor Demand in the market in the short run.
Frank Cowell: Efficiency-Waste EFFICIENCY: WASTE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Welfare and Efficiency Almost essential.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
Chapter 15 The Physician’s Practice
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Elasticity and Its Application
Health System Reform © Allen C. Goodman, Major Themes Lower costs, or lower growth in costs. Provision of (more) equitable access to care for.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply
Elasticity and Its Application
You design websites for local businesses
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Elasticity... … allows us to analyze supply and demand with greater precision. … is a measure of how much buyers and sellers.
Part 5 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Perfect Competition.
By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Elasticity and Consumer Surplus
1 Applications of Rational Choice APEC 3001 Summer 2007 Readings: Chapter 5 in Frank.
REVENUE THEORY IB Business & Management A Course Companion 2009 THE THEORY OF THE FIRM: COSTS, REVENUES AND PROFITS.
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
Micro Chapter 7 Consumer Choice and Elasticity.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Chapter 20 Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation Social efficiency is maximized at the competitive equilibrium (in the absence.
Drill: Oct. 3, 2013 Why do people complain about gasoline prices going up but continue to fill up their tank? Do you think there is a price increase at.
Chapter 5 Part 2 notes $7 Demand is elastic; demand is responsive to changes in price. Demand is inelastic; demand is.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
ECO1000 Economics Semester One, 2004 Lecture Four.
THE THEORY OF DEMAND & SUPPLY
Demand Elasticities and Related Coefficients. Demand Curve Demand curves are assumed to be downward sloping, but the responsiveness of quantity (Q) to.
Elasticity and its Applications. Learn the meaning of the elasticity of demand. Examine what determines the elasticity of demand. Learn the meaning of.
Demand and Supply Elasticity
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 5 Elasticity and Its Applications.
ELASTICITY AND ITS APPLICATIONS
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
Understanding Demand What is the law of demand?
The Theory of Consumer Choice
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
Chapter 8 The Costs of Taxation Ratna K. Shrestha.
1 Education 1 - Funding © Allen C. Goodman, 2008.
1 Elasticity of Demand and Supply CHAPTER 5 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Elasticity of Demand and Supply CHERYL CARLETON ASHER Villanova University Chapter 5 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
Economics Unit Three Part I: Demand. Demand Essentially, demand is the willingness (or desire) to buy a good or service and the ability to pay for it.
Elasticity of Demand Chapter 5. Slope of Demand Curves Demand curves do not all have the same slope Slope indicates response of buyers to a change in.
Next page Chapter 5: The Demand for Labor. Jump to first page 1. Derived Demand for Labor.
UNDERSTANDING DEMAND This section will be one of the easiest to understand. You live out this section nearly every day. SUMMARY OF SECTION – This section.
1 Education 1 - Funding © Allen C. Goodman, 2014.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities Chapter 6.
HOW MUCH MORE OR LESS? DOES IT MATTER? THE LAW OF DEMAND SAYS... Consumers will buy more when prices go down and less when prices go up 1.
Elasticity and Its Application
Lecture 7: What is Regression Analysis? BUEC 333 Summer 2009 Simon Woodcock.
Answers to Review Questions  1.Explain the difference between aggregate demand and the aggregate quantity demanded of real output. Ceteris paribus, how.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Topic 3 Elasticity Topic 3 Elasticity. Elasticity a Fancy Term  Elasticity is a fancy term for a simple concept  Whenever you see the word elasticity,
Elasticity and its Application CHAPTER 5. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: What is elasticity? What kinds of issues can elasticity.
Taxation Frederick University 2009.
1 Stephen Chiu University of Hong Kong Elasticity.
Review of the previous lecture
Economic Perspectives. » DEMAND: The amount of goods/services consumers are willing & able to buy at various prices during a specified time period. »
Public Economics UC3M 2015 DEADWEIGHT COST AGZ 2.1 and Gruber.
Consumer Welfare 1. 2 One way to evaluate the welfare cost of a price increase (from p x 0 to p x 1 ) would be to compare the expenditures required to.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
© 2011 Cengage South-Western. © 2007 Thomson South-Western Elasticity... … allows us to analyze supply and demand with greater precision. … is a measure.
Demand Analysis. Elasticity... … allows us to analyze supply and demand with greater precision. … is a measure of how much buyers and sellers respond.
Changes in Equilibrium!. Equilibrium Review Equilibrium is where quantity supplied and quantity demanded are equal. Graphically, equilibrium is the point.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 11 th Edition, Copyright 2012 PowerPoint prepared by.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. TAXATION AND GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION TAXATION AND GOVERNMENT.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Consumer Choice and Elasticity
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Chapter 4: Section 1 Understanding Demand
Presentation transcript:

SID, SAV, and Efficient Use Chapter 15 © Allen C. Goodman, 2013

Supplier Induced Demand Does more providers  more treatment? S1S1 S2S2 D1D1 D2D2 D'2D'2 Price of Services Quantity of Services P1P1 Q1Q1 Suppose S  from S 1 to S 2. You would expect changes to P 3, Q 3. Q3Q3 P3P3 If physicians can induce demand, however, to D 2, or D' 2, they can avoid losses. What kind of evidence do we need.

Big Econometric Identification Problem Start with model without SID (From earlier editions – not in FGS/5 – 7) Q D = a 0 + a 1 P + a 2 Y + u 1 (10.1) Q S = b 0 + b 1 P + b 2 X + b 3 MD + u 2 (10.2) where MD is number of MDs. In Eq’m: a 0 + a 1 P + a 2 Y + u 1 = Q D = Q S = b 0 + b 1 P + b 2 X + b 3 MD + u 2 or P = (b 0 -a 0 )/(a 1 -b 1 ) - a 2 Y /(a 1 -b 1 ) +b 2 X/ (a 1 -b 1 ) + b 3 MD/ (a 1 -b 1 ) Substituting into either (10.1) or (10.2) Q = c 0 + c 2 X + c 3 Y + c 4 MD + v(10.3) This looks like SID, except there was no SID in the model.

Why not induce all the time? Perhaps, inducement is a “bad.” Gives us unusual indifference curves. We see U 1 > U 2. Inducement, I Net Income U1U1 U 2 < U 1 I2I2 I1I1 p = mQ 0 + mI Suppose m falls (due to increased competition). It could give us less inducement … or more inducement. mQ 0 m Q0m Q0 I3I3 U' 2 < U 1 m = profit rate Can not have BOTH U 2 and U' 2

Let’s decompose a decrease in m into income and substitution effects Suppose m falls Inducement, I Net Income U1U1 U 2 < U 1 I2I2 I1I1 p = mQ 0 + mI Income effect – Drop in m implies more inducement Substitution effect – Drop in m makes inducement less effective. We do less inducement. Income and Substitution Effects Income Effect Substitution Effect m = profit rate

Suggests that for there to be major increase in inducement, income effects must dominate substitution effects. Research findings, at this point are varied. Inducement, I Net Income U1U1 U 2 < U 1 I2I2 I1I1 p = mQ 0 + mI Income and Substitution Effects Income Effect Substitution Effect m = profit rate

Important Issue If you believe in SID, then demand-side policies have little impact because providers can always induce more demand. Some people argue that of course providers induce demand – if so, so do mechanics.

SAV – Small Area Variation Is the Right Amount of Treatment Used? Usage of technologies may vary. Why? –Provider may not have complete knowledge of patient’s condition. –May not have complete knowledge of appropriateness of procedure. –Provider may have preferences among types of treatment. –Patient may have preferences among types of treatment.

Wennberg Practice style -- Why do practices vary so much? Medical Care Health Status S1S1 S2S2 S* Medical Care Health StatusS1S1 S2S2 S* Mgl. Cost Phys. 2 is shown as believing that additional units of medical care are more effective than does Phys. 1 Rate w/in a market depends on distributions of type 1 and type 2 Phys. M1M1 M2M2 Mgl. Product May vary within same office!

An Example Cesarean sections. Reference: Dartmouth Atlas for Michigan, Pp 8-9.Dartmouth Atlas for Michigan What does it mean?

McAllen v. El Paso Both cities on Rio Grande River. Both with large Hispanic percentages. McAllen – 89% El Paso – 82% Source: Franzini et al.Franzini et al.

Gawande What’s going on? Gawande A. The cost conundrum.New Yorker [serial on the Internet] Jun 1 [cited 2010 Nov 3].Available from:

Franzini, Mikhail, Skinner Look at medical use and expense data for patients privately insured by Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Texas. In contrast to the Medicare, use of and spending per capita for medical services by privately insured populations in McAllen and El Paso was much less divergent, with some exceptions. Although spending per Medicare member per year was 86% higher in McAllen than in El Paso, total spending per member per year in McAllen was 7% lower than in El Paso for the population insured by BCBS of Texas. Conclude that health care providers respond differently to Medicare incentives compared to private insurance.

Gawande A. The cost conundrum.New Yorker [serial on the Internet] Jun 1 [cited 2010 Nov 3].Available from:

How do we test it? Education, Feedback, and Surveillance –If by providing education, or by monitoring certain types of treatments, there is a change  Practice Style Hypothesis. Some verification, but not a lot. Comparing Utilization Rates in Homogeneous Areas –If you can rule out utilization differences due to socioeconomic factors, you can say that practice style is important. Control by regression analysis. If you do a regression: Utilization =  b i x i + e, then if you’ve controlled for everything, you get an R 2 measure. Practice style would be the residual.

Three Problems How do you know if you’ve controlled for everything? What if some of your x’s actually represent practice style. Most of this is decidedly ad hoc. You’d like to see some good modeling. When done, we explain between 40 and 75% of the variation. This may leave a little, or a lot of variation to be explained by practice style.

SAV and Inappropriate Care Can you look at different levels of care, and determine that something wrong is going on. A> No! Efficient use of care occurs where marginal benefits = marginal costs. Simplest way to define this is to look at supply and demand curves. You may have single demand curve, and differing supply curves, due, e.g. to factor conditions Medical Care $ D1D1 S1S1 $ D1D1 S1S1 D2D2 S2S2 Demand? Supply?

SAV and Inappropriate Care OR, Differing demand curves due to incomes, preferences, et. Medical Care $ D1D1 S1S1 D2D2

+ - Inappropriate Levels of Care If Q 1 is the “right” level, then What are the costs of being at the wrong level, Either + or -? Medical Care $ D1D1 S1S1 Q1Q1

Measuring the costs in the aggregate Fundamentally, we'll assume that marginal cost is constant. If marginal costs are rising, we'll see that these constitute lower bounds to the true costs. (1) W = 0.5   x i  v i Why? W = welfare loss x i = utilization of intervention for person i v i = valuation of incremental unit IF  is the correct utilization, (2) W = 0.5  (x i -  )  v i Loss triangles !

If we then multiply and divide (3) by  2, we get [write out]: W = 0.5 E  2 Nv/  W = (0.5 E  2 /  2 )(Nv/  )  2 Coefficient of variation =  / , so  2 /  2 is CV 2. Measuring the costs (2) Suppose that the valuation function is:  =  v/  x, or  v =  (x i -  ). Substituting into (2): (3) W = 0.5   (x i -  ) (x i -  ) = 0.5   2 N. Define inverse elasticity, at the mean, as: E = (dV/dx)(x/V) =   /v   = E v/ . x v xx vv Slope =  (2) W = 0.5  (x i -  )  vi xixi 

That leaves Nv , which equals aggregate spending. W = 0.5 * E * CV 2 * Spending Level. I like working in terms of real Elasticities, so I would use: W = 0.5 * CV 2 * Spending Level/E'. where E' is the true demand elasticity, and CV 2 is the coefficient of variation squared. Coefficient of variation is defined as the standard deviation divided by the mean. A good descriptive measure but it doesn't have a lot of statistical theory attached to it. Measuring the costs (3)

Measuring the costs (4) So this says that careful study of a medical intervention will have a greater expected benefit when: - large numbers of people are affected. - the per-unit cost of the intervention is high. - the level of uncertainty about correct use is large. - demand is inelastic. W = 0.5 * CV 2 * Spending Level/E'.

What if we use mean rather than X*? What may happen if we are comparing the actual use with the mean, when, instead, we should be using X*, the appropriate level? Consider valuation curves V 1 and V 2, their average V a, and the appropriate level V*. If we compute the welfare loss around average X a, we would include areas A, B, and C. The correct measure has areas A, C, D, E, and F, but not B. Measured Loss = A + B + C True Loss = A + D + E + F + C

B Rate of Use Incremental Value MC V* VA V2 V1 X1X1 X*X*XaXa X2X2 A C D E F Measured Loss = A + B + C True Loss = A + D + E + F + C True - Measured = (A + D + E + F + C) - (A + B + C) T - M = (D + E)

Measured Loss = A + B + C True Loss = A + D + E + F + C True - Measured = (A + D + E + F + C) - (A + B + C) T - M = (D + E) Region F has the same area as region B, so the missing area has size of regions D and E combined which is a parallelogram. So you are underestimating by (D + E). Of course, if marginal costs are increasing, the losses are even larger. What if we use mean rather than X*?