Measuring Inefficiencies from Adverse Selection Jonathan Levin Gaston Eyskens Lectures November 7, 2013.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Competition and the Market
Advertisements

Fall 2008 Version Professor Dan C. Jones FINA 4355 Class Problem.
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
Chapter 9: Health Care Market
Health Insurance – Part 1 Eric Jacobson. Employer Health Benefits 2004 Annual Survey Kaiser Family Foundation
Teleconference 2 1.Guest speakers in May 2.Policy Brief Project The Employer and Health Insurance.
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Fehr and Falk Wage Rigidity in a Competitive Incomplete Contract Market Economics 328 Spring 2005.
Heterogeneity One limitation of the static LS model lies in the heterogeneity assumption. In reality, individuals differ in preference and in information.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 20/1 Chapter 20 Asymmetric Information and Market Behaviour.
Chapter 6 Labour Market. Outline.  The perfectly competitive model of the labour market  Imperfect competition on the labour market  Further topics.
Health Insurance October 19, 2006 Insurance is defined as a means of protecting against risk. Risk is a state in which multiple outcomes are possible and.
317_L17, Feb 13, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of the case for public health insurance basic reason => market failure.
317_L12, Feb 1, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture discussed the effect of proportional health insurance on the healthcare market => showed.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Health System Reform © Allen C. Goodman, Major Themes Lower costs, or lower growth in costs. Provision of (more) equitable access to care for.
Chapter 8 Demand and Supply of Health Insurance 1.What is Insurance 2.Risk and Insurance 3.The demand for Insurance 4.The supply for Insurance 5.The case.
Health Insurance Decisions, Expectations, and Job Turnover Randall P. Ellis Boston University and UTS-CHERE Albert Ma Boston University.
1 INS301 Chp16 Employee Benefits: Overview and Group Medical Coverage Overview of employ benefits Group medical insurance Background of health care market.
Health Insurance – Part 2 Eric Jacobson. Key Definitions Adverse selection – Enrollees may seek to join a health plan at a premium that reflects a lower.
The role of insurance in health care, part 1
Lectures Section Seven: Market Failure Introduction to Microeconomics (L11100)
317_L11, Jan 30, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of health insurance and its impact on the healthcare market Defined.
How insurance affects the demand for medical care
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Chapter 6: Health Insurance Chapter 6 Health Insurance Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Entrepreneurship and Public Policy Lecture 8: The Implications of the U.S. Health Insurance System for Entrepreneurship.
The Private Health Insurance Market. Insurance Design Insurance is designed to spread risk Individuals can self-insure and face chance of paying for costs.
Pricing Policies chapter 18
THE HEALTH CARE MARKET Chapter 9.
Chapter 5: Demand and Supply
Insurance Fundamentals for Policymakers. Four assignments: Insurance Principles Insurance Coverages: Property and Casualty Insurance Coverages: Life and.
By David M. Cutler, Amy Finkelstein, and Kathleen McGarry* American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2008, 98:2, 157–162.
Asymmetric Information and Agency. Overview and Background Traditional models of demand side assume that individuals have complete information about prices.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Risk Management & Insurance
Click on the button to go to the problem © 2013 Pearson.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
Copyright 2007 Thomson South-Western Chapter 6 Personal Risk Management.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Asymmetric Information
Enhanced Annuities, Individual Underwriting, and Adverse Selection August 6, Enhanced Annuities, Individual Underwriting, and Adverse Selection.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 7-1 Defining Competitiveness Chapter 7.
Employee Choice of a Consumer Driven Health Plan in a Multi-Plan, Multi-Product Setting Stephen T. Parente, Roger Feldman, Jon B. Christianson University.
Monopolistic Competition
Asymmetric Information
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Chapter 13: Predatory Conduct: recent developments 1 Predatory Conduct: Recent Developments.
Do State Parity Laws Differentially Impact Low Income or High Need Groups? Colleen L. Barry, Ph.D. Susan H. Busch, Ph.D. Yale School of Medicine June 2006.
Market Failure 11 Farid Abolhassani.
Review Monopoly Summary A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller in its market. It faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product. A.
Private Health Insurance
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 6-1 CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all.
C HAPTER 3 CONTINUED Market Failure. W HAT IS MARKET FAILURE ? Market Failure exists when the free market system fails to allocate resources in an efficient.
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
Fiscal aspects of health systems William Jack Georgetown University Motivated by “The fiscal sustainability of health care in Canada” Gregory Marchildon,
Premium Sensitivity Among Workers Chapter What Is the Relevant Premium? The “risk premium”? The “risk premium”? The “loading fee”? The “loading.
1 Measuring the Welfare Effect of Entry in Differentiated Product Markets: The Case of Medicare HMOs Shiko Maruyama University of New South Wales 19 June,
PRELIMINARY-PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE Trends & Determinants of Self- insuring Health Benefits Philip F. Cooper Kosali I. Simon.
Refuting The Republican Healthcare Proposal
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
Health Insurance: Introduction
Adverse selection Abhinash adhikari Astha gyawali Bijay chalise
Presentation transcript:

Measuring Inefficiencies from Adverse Selection Jonathan Levin Gaston Eyskens Lectures November 7, 2013

Roadmap Lectures 1.Technology and Asymmetric Information 2.High Risk Consumer Credit Markets 3.Measuring Inefficiencies from Adverse Selection 4.Can Markets for Health Insurance Work?

Introduction  Generally taken for granted that asymmetric information creates significant inefficiencies in insurance markets.  Several related types of inefficiency: – Mispricing due to adverse selection – Distortion of available products – Complete market breakdown  Today’s lecture: describe recent work on two questions. – Can we detect asymmetric information in insurance markets? – Can we estimate the welfare losses from adverse selection?  Based on Einav, Finkelstein, Levin (2010, Ann Rev), and especially Bundorf, Levin, Mahoney (2012, AER).

Testing for Adverse Selection  Key prediction: People who are higher risk buy more insurance. -This self-selection drives up the price of generous insurance, so equilibrium coverage is inefficiently low.  Seems easy to test … – Identify people who choose “more” versus “less” insurance while facing the same prices (important if self-selection is to apply). – Look ex post to see who makes a claim or costs more to cover. – If individuals who buy more insurance have higher realized risk, taken as evidence for the theory. If not, evidence against the theory.  Moral hazard complicates interpretation: Individuals might generate more claims because they have more insurance.

Evidence: Puelz and Snow (JPE, 1994)  Sample of 3,280 individuals who bought auto collision insurance in Georgia in 1986, choosing deductible level. Deductible Level $100$200$250 Number of individuals 1, ,192 Number incurring a loss Fraction w/ loss3.03%2.28%1.59%  Regression of deductible choice on indicator for a subsequent loss, controlling for the prices of the different plans, shows deductible choices is correlated with loss conditional on Xs.

Evidence: Chiappori and Salanie (JPE 2000)  Large sample of auto insurance contracts in France in  Test whether deductible choice is correlated with having subsequent accident, conditional on individual characteristics used in pricing.  Main finding: cannot reject that conditional on (rich) covariates: deductible choice is not correlated with driver having an accident.  Interpretation: if rich individual data is used for pricing, there may not be much self-selection within risk categories.

Evidence: Life Insurance and Long-Term Care  Cawley and Philipsson (AER 1999) on life insurance – People with more life insurance have lower mortality than those with less insurance, and lower self-reported risk of death.  Finkelstein-McGarry (AER 2005) on long-term care insurance – No correlation between LTC insurance and subsequent use. – Although people who say that they expect to use a nursing home are more likely to buy LTC insurance, and more likely to use LTC. – Interpretation: there is an offsetting effect, e.g. wealthier people are more likely to buy insurance but less likely to need LTC.

Evidence: Hendren (EMA 2013)

From Testing to Measurement  Lessons from testing papers – Extent of adverse selection seems to vary across markets, depending on what is priced, and specific nature of risk.  In markets where risk is not accurately priced, can we quantify how important are the distortions? – This requires some additional structure. – Need to understand how “incorrect” pricing affects choices. And need to understand cost structure to measure the misallocation, and whether key products aren’t offered.  Remainder of the talk – Outline “textbook” model of insurance demand + welfare. – Two applications using slightly stylized approaches.

Canonical Insurance Model

Measuring Welfare

Modeling Adverse Selection  Einav-Finkelstein-Cullen (2011, QJE) – Employees at a large employer (Alcoa) choosing more or less generous health insurance. – Health care costs are higher for employees who chose the more generous coverage.  Linear model of demand and costs, as a function of price. – Prices faced by the employees varied by location. – Estimate using data on insurance choices and claims. – Measure welfare as the difference between WTP and cost.

Einav-Finkelstein-Cullen Linear Model Quantity Price Demand Avg Cost Marg. Cost Efficient Q Comp. Q P =AC P =MC As price decreases, more people buy (extra) insurance The cost of covering the extra enrollees is lower – they’re healthier.

Measuring Adverse Selection Estimates from Einav, Finkelstein and Cullen (2010, QJE): Data from Alcoa Deadweight loss from adverse selection is not that large. Why? Because demand is inelastic!

Modeling Self-Selection  Bundorf, Levin and Mahoney (2012, AER)  Choice between differentiated health plans – An “integrated HMO” plan with specific doctors. – A traditional “PPO” insurance plan. – Choice isn’t just more/less generous insurance  No obvious problem of adverse selection, but … will see that self-selection can still create inefficiencies.

Self-Selection with Differentiation

Self-Selection and Inefficiency Risk (  ) WTP Δv Δc(  ) Assume: (1) plan A relatively more effective at covering high cost patients; (2) prices aren’t personalized. ΔpΔp Choose B efficiently Choose A efficiently Choose B inefficiently Choose A inefficiently

Data and Environment  Data from a company that helps small to mid-sized employers offer choice of health insurance plans.  How the plan choice process works – Insurers submit bids to cover employees at a firm. – Firm sets employee premiums. – Employees select plans.  Data includes bids, premiums, employee info, including predictive risk scores, plan choices and subsequent costs.  As noted above, plans provided by two insurers – a (low-cost) “integrated” and a (higher-cost) standard insurer.

Key Features of the Environment 1.Standard insurer is higher cost, especially for less healthy people. – Standard insurer has higher average ex post costs and also bids higher, with difference most pronounced for high-risk (less-healthy) people. 2.Individuals at a firm face the same subsidized plan prices, not dependent on individual health status (federal regulation). – Individual premiums are higher for standard insurer. Average premiums are $41 for integrated and $54 for standard insurer. 3.Majority of individuals choose the low-priced integrated insurer. – 71% compared to 29% for standard insurer. 4.No obvious adverse selection – Enrollee risk is 1.02 for standard insurer versus 0.99 for integrated.

Cost Structure of Insurers

Bids of Insurers

Puzzling Feature of Pricing

BLM Empirical Model

Estimating Insurance Demand + Costs  Household demand for health plans – Little evidence of important risk-based preferences. – Relatively little price elasticity, in line with other studies.  Optimal assignment by risk score – As risk increases from 1 to 2.5, WTP for standard insurer increases by $22, but incremental cost increases by $101.  Efficient to put high-cost individuals into low-cost plan, but to provide price incentive for this sort of self-selection, requires making high-cost plan very expensive for all individuals…

Inefficiency in the Estimated Model

Assessing Inefficiency  Calculate social surplus under alternative types of pricing -Efficient: each household faces actuarially fair prices. -Feasible: each household faces prices equal to predicted costs, not including private information. -Uniform: employees at each firm face most efficient uniform prices, i.e. independent of their health status. -Actual: uniform prices as observed in data, not optimal.  Main finding: differences in social surplus are relatively modest, about 2-11% of coverage costs. -Could eliminate ¼ with optimal uniform prices. -Could eliminate ½ with risk-rated individual prices.

Assessing Inefficiency

Welfare and Consumer Choice  EFC and BLM (and other recent studies) find very modest welfare losses from adverse / self-selection.  Main reason is inelastic demand – Typical finding in studies of (health) insurance. – Why does it matter? The source of inefficiency is that individuals don’t face efficient personalized prices. – With inelastic demand, price distortions don’t have much effect on the allocation, which is what matters for efficiency!  So … why isn’t demand more price-sensitive?

Switching Costs / Inertia?  Handel (2013, AER) Example Existing EmployeesNew Employees Available PlansYear 1Year 2 PPO %21%11% PPO %26%43% PPO %14% HMOs (A+B)40%39%32%  Choices are very persistent. The surprise here is that in Year 2, the price of PPO 250 went up so much that PPO 500 was cheaper regardless of how much care you got – and yet people picked it.

Inertia and Adverse Selection  Handel goes on to study a more general model of choice – similar to above, but incorporating switching costs.  Finds that inertia in plan choice helps explain inelastic demand and (to some extent) failure to find inefficiencies from adverse selection.  Then makes an interesting observation … forcing active decisions in insurance markets: – Increases price sensitivity and potentially avoids dominated choices, but also exacerbates adverse selection, by creating more sorting / self-selection.

Missing Pieces  Choice Behavior – Insurance products are complicated, and unlike in these models consumers choose poorly (Handel + Kolstad, others).  Moral Hazard – Talk has focused on adverse selection problems, and not on moral hazard, through which insurance affects behavior. – Maybe not a big deal in life insurance and annuities, or even auto insurance. But a very big deal in health insurance.  Reclassification Risk – Risk-based pricing helps mitigate adverse selection, but it creates re-classification risk: individuals who get (persistently) sick in year t will face high risk-rated prices in years t+1, t+2, etc.

Competition  Papers I’ve discussed do not focus on competition – Einav et al.: just assumes p = AC – Bundorf et al: prices set by administrative rules  But unlike in our models, insurance markets often have a limited set of firms and presumably imperfect competition.  Raises some questions for next lecture – Are inefficiencies from imperfect competition a bigger issue than inefficiencies from adverse selection? – What sort of models can we use to analyze markets where there is self-selection and imperfect competition?

Summary  Recent work has begun to explore and measure the extent of self- selection in insurance markets and the resulting distortions.  Exciting area – rich data and interesting theories to analyze large and economically important markets.  Mixed evidence on importance of adverse selection – Risk-based pricing seems to offset AS in many settings. – In others, can observe clear self-selection, but misallocation of resources does not seem large. – Of course, some markets simply may not exist … the inefficiency from “missing markets” could be large.  Plenty of missing pieces for future work!

Extra Slides