Classical Economics & Relative Prices. Classical Economics Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Classical economics relies on three main.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Currencies and Exchange Rates To buy goods and services produced in another country we need money of that country. Foreign bank notes, coins, and.
Advertisements

A Macroeconomic Theory of the Open-Economy. Outline:  Develop a model to study forces that determine the open economy variables (NX, NFI, RER)  How.
Interest Rates in the Classical Model Nominal vs.. Real Interest Rates Real interest rate =Nominal rate - Inflation rate  = r- 
Ch. 18: International Finance
Ch. 9: The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments.
Ch. 9: The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments.
Open Economy Macroeconomics The Final Frontier. Closed Economy Macroeconomics Y = C + I + G (Goods Market) S = I + (G-T) (Asset Market) There is only.
Slide 15-1Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. The Law of One Price Identical goods sold in different countries must sell for the same price when their.
FIN 40500: International Finance Nominal Rigidities and Exchange Rate Volatility.
The link between domestic savings, foreign savings, and domestic investment
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 15 Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long.
Slide 15-1Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Exchange rates and the Foreign Exchange Market Money, Interest Rates and Exchange Rates  Price Levels.
The Open Economy Chapter 8 - Mankiw.
Chapter 18 A Macroeconomic Theory Of the Open Economy
Chapter 18 Exchange Rate Determination I: Prices and the Real Exchange Rate.
Ch. 10: The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments.
VI. Purchasing Power Parity Read Chapter 4, pp. 102 ‑ The Law of One Price (LOP) LOP Conditions for LOP to hold 2. Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)
© 2011 Pearson Education Why has our dollar been sinking? One U.S. dollar was worth 1.17 euros in 2001 but only 68 euro cents in Why?
Chapter 16 Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run.
Preview: 9/29, 10/1 Quiz: Yfe … P … E
Currency Analysis with Fundamentals. Fundamental Analysis involves the use of data to assess the strength/weakness of a currency Economic Data GDP Employment.
Ec 335 International Trade and Finance
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Monetary Approach to Exchange Rates (cont.) A change in the money supply results in.
Macroeconomics (ECON 1211) Lecturer: Dr B. M. Nowbutsing Topic: Open economy macroeconomics.
Economics 282 University of Alberta
26 CHAPTER The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments.
Copyright © 2001 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Slide Exchange Rates and the Open Economy.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. The Canadian dollar is one of 100s of different monies. The three big monies: the U.S. dollar, yen, and euro. In February.
THEORIES OF FOREIGN EXCHANGE International Parity Conditions.
Chapter Fourteen Economic Interdependence. Copyright © Houghton Mifflin Company. All rights reserved.14 | 2 Countries are not independent of one another;
1 Section 4 The Exchange Rate in the Long Run. 2 Content Objectives Purchasing Power Parity A Long-Run PPP Model The Real Exchange Rate Summary.
Exchange Rate Volatility and Keynesian Economics.
INTERNATIONAL FINANCE 18 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how international trade is financed  Describe a.
KYIV SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS I September-October 2013 Instructor: Maksym Obrizan Lecture notes IV # 2. CHAPTER 5 The open economy So far we.
Luxembourg 275.5% Ireland Czech Republic Hungary 134.5
International Economics
Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 15 Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run.
Unit 3: Exchange Rates Foreign Exchange 3/21/2012.
Chapter 23. Aggregate demand and aggregate supply in the open economy ECON320 Prof Mike Kennedy.
© 2013 Pearson. Why has our dollar been sinking?
Mankiw: Brief Principles of Macroeconomics, Second Edition (Harcourt, 2001) Ch. 12: Open Economy Macroeconomics: Basic Concepts.
The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments 25.
Thank You for Attention. Explain how the foreign exchange market works. Examine the forces that determine exchange rates. Consider whether it is possible.
PARITY CONDITIONS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE
OPEN ECONOMY MACRO AND THE EXCHANGE RATE (1) Up to now, we have ignored the exchange rate: i.e. the price of foreign currency in terms of domestic currency.
Fundamental Analysis Classical vs. Keynesian. Similarities Both the classical approach and the Keynesian approach are macro models and, hence, examine.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley CHAPTER 1. © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
Exchange Rates. An exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of another. –It indicates how many units of one currency can be bought with a single.
Unit 3: Monetary Policy Foreign Exchange 11/4/2010.
Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs An Introduction to International Economics Chapter 12: Exchange Rate Determination Dominick.
Exchange Rate Models With Nominal Rigidities Available Assets Home Currency (M) Pays no interest, but needed to buy goods Domestic Bonds (B) Pays interest.
Chapter 15 Supplementary Notes.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 21: Exchange Rates, International Trade, and Capital.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Preview Law of one price Purchasing power parity Long run model of exchange rates: monetary.
12-1 Issue 14 – Determination of exchange rates Extracted from Krugman and Obstfeld – International Economics ECON3315 International Economic Issues Instructor:
1 International Finance Chapter 16 Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run.
9 THE EXCHANGE RATE AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS © 2014 Pearson Addison-Wesley After studying this chapter, you will be able to:  Explain how the exchange.
The Monetary Approach to Exchange Rates Putting Everything Together.
Exchange Rates. An exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of another. –It indicates how many units of one currency can be bought with a single.
The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder? 19.
Chapter Five 1 CHAPTER 5 The Open Economy ® A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 6th. ed. N. Gregory Mankiw By Mannig J. Simidian.
Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run.
26 THE EXCHANGE RATE AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS.
Financial System:Loanable Fund and Exchange Markets IMBA Macroeconomics II Lecturer: Jack Wu.
Macro Chapter 9 An Introduction to Basic Macroeconomic Markets.
26 THE EXCHANGE RATE AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS.
Foreign Exchange Markets, ECO Money & Banking - Dr. D. Foster Purchasing Power Parity, and Real Interest Parity.
Review of the previous lecture
Presentation transcript:

Classical Economics & Relative Prices

Classical Economics Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Classical economics relies on three main assumptions:

Classical Economics Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Markets are perfectly competitive Markets are perfectly competitive All prices are flexible All prices are flexible Markets clear (equilibrium) Markets clear (equilibrium)

Classical Economics Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Markets are perfectly competitive Markets are perfectly competitive All prices are flexible All prices are flexible Markets clear (equilibrium) Markets clear (equilibrium) One key result is that all real variables are independent of monetary policy (money neutrality) One key result is that all real variables are independent of monetary policy (money neutrality)

Savings, Investment, and the Trade Balance Recall that in a closed economy, demand for loanable funds (supply of marketable securities) must equal the supply of loanable funds (demand for marketable securities) Recall that in a closed economy, demand for loanable funds (supply of marketable securities) must equal the supply of loanable funds (demand for marketable securities)

Savings, Investment, and the Trade Balance Recall that in a closed economy, demand for loanable funds (supply of marketable securities) must equal the supply of loanable funds (demand for marketable securities) Recall that in a closed economy, demand for loanable funds (supply of marketable securities) must equal the supply of loanable funds (demand for marketable securities) S = I + (G-T) S = Private Savings I = Private Investment (G-T) = Government Deficit/Surplus

Savings/Investment in a Closed Economy Without access to world capital markets, a country’s private saving is the sole source of funds. Therefore, the domestic interest rate must adjust to insure that S = I + (G-T) Without access to world capital markets, a country’s private saving is the sole source of funds. Therefore, the domestic interest rate must adjust to insure that S = I + (G-T) In this example, the domestic interest rate is equal to 10% and S = I +(G-T) = 300 In this example, the domestic interest rate is equal to 10% and S = I +(G-T) = 300 What will happen if we expose this country to trade? What will happen if we expose this country to trade?

Savings in the Open Economy In an open economy, the rest of the world becomes an added source of demand/supply of marketable securities In an open economy, the rest of the world becomes an added source of demand/supply of marketable securities S = I + (G-T) + NX Further, perfect capital mobility insures that all countries have the same (risk adjusted) real interest rate.

Savings in the Open Economy Again, a trade deficit implies NX<0 Again, a trade deficit implies NX<0 Therefore, S – (I – (G-T)) = NX < 0 Therefore, S – (I – (G-T)) = NX < 0

Savings in the Open Economy Again, a trade deficit implies NX<0 Again, a trade deficit implies NX<0 Therefore, S – (I – (G-T)) = NX < 0 Therefore, S – (I – (G-T)) = NX < 0 A country with a trade deficit is borrowing from the rest of the world A country with a trade deficit is borrowing from the rest of the world That is, domestic supply of marketable securities is greater than domestic demand That is, domestic supply of marketable securities is greater than domestic demand

Adding Net Exports to Capital Markets Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 6% Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 6%

Adding Net Exports to Capital Markets Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 6% Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 6% At 6%, At 6%, S = $100 S = $100 I + (G-T) = $500 I + (G-T) = $500 NX = $100 - $500 = - $400 NX = $100 - $500 = - $400

Adding Net Exports to Capital Markets Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 14% Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 14%

Adding Net Exports to Capital Markets Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 14% Suppose that the prevailing world (real) interest rate is 14% S = $500 S = $500 I + (G-T) = $100 I + (G-T) = $100 NX = $500 - $100 = $400 NX = $500 - $100 = $400

Where does the world interest rate come from? Aggregate world savings is the sum of private savings across countries Aggregate world savings is the sum of private savings across countries Aggregate Private Investment and Government Deficits are also summed over all countries Aggregate Private Investment and Government Deficits are also summed over all countries By definition, NX summed over all countries must equal zero. Therefore, at the real world equilibrium interest rate, By definition, NX summed over all countries must equal zero. Therefore, at the real world equilibrium interest rate, S = I + (G-T) In this example, r = 11% In this example, r = 11%

Example: An increase in productivity Suppose that trade is initially balanced. A rise in productivity increases investment demand Suppose that trade is initially balanced. A rise in productivity increases investment demand

Example: An increase in productivity Suppose that trade is initially balanced. A rise in productivity increases investment demand Suppose that trade is initially balanced. A rise in productivity increases investment demand In a closed economy, interest rates would rise In a closed economy, interest rates would rise

Example: An increase in productivity Suppose that trade is initially balanced. A rise in productivity increases investment demand Suppose that trade is initially balanced. A rise in productivity increases investment demand In a closed economy, interest rates would rise In a closed economy, interest rates would rise In an open economy, the trade deficit would increase. In the case, the deficit increases from zero to - $15,000 In an open economy, the trade deficit would increase. In the case, the deficit increases from zero to - $15,000 Do interest rates rise at all? Do interest rates rise at all?

World Capital Markets A country’s ability to influence world interest rates depends on its size relative to the world economy (recall, global interest rates are determined such that global capital markets clear) A country’s ability to influence world interest rates depends on its size relative to the world economy (recall, global interest rates are determined such that global capital markets clear) The US makes up roughly 35% of the global economy. Therefore, the US can significantly influence global interest rates (as can Japan, EU, and China) The US makes up roughly 35% of the global economy. Therefore, the US can significantly influence global interest rates (as can Japan, EU, and China) The rest of the world has little influence unless it acts as a unified group (Latin American Financial Crisis, Asian Crisis) The rest of the world has little influence unless it acts as a unified group (Latin American Financial Crisis, Asian Crisis)

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E P* = E190 (E Price in Europe)

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E What should happen here? What should happen here? P* = E190 (E Price in Europe) eP* = ($1.17/E)(E190) = $222.30

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E For example, suppose that the price of a television is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe. The current exchange rate is $1.17/E What should happen here? What should happen here? A profit can be made by buying TVs in the US and selling them in Europe. A profit can be made by buying TVs in the US and selling them in Europe. P* = E190 (E Price in Europe) eP* = ($1.17/E)(E190) = $222.30

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP*

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* If the price of a TV is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe, the implied exchange rate is $1.05/E If the price of a TV is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe, the implied exchange rate is $1.05/E

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* If the price of a TV is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe, the implied exchange rate is $1.05/E If the price of a TV is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe, the implied exchange rate is $1.05/E P = $200 P* = E190 P = eP*

Exchange Rates and Price Levels The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location The Law of One Price (LOOP) states that the same product should cost the same in every location LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* LOOP states that in equilibrium, no such profits can occur. Therefore, P = eP* If the price of a TV is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe, the implied exchange rate is $1.05/E If the price of a TV is $200 in the US and E190 in Europe, the implied exchange rate is $1.05/E P = $200 P* = E190 P = eP* e = P/P* = $200/E190 = $1.05/E

Purchasing Power Parity Purchasing power parity (PPP) is simply LOOP applied to general price indices Purchasing power parity (PPP) is simply LOOP applied to general price indices P = eP*

Purchasing Power Parity Purchasing power parity (PPP) is simply LOOP applied to general price indices Purchasing power parity (PPP) is simply LOOP applied to general price indices P = eP* A more useful form of PPP is A more useful form of PPP is %Change in e = Inflation – Inflation*

Purchasing Power Parity Purchasing power parity (PPP) is simply LOOP applied to general price indices Purchasing power parity (PPP) is simply LOOP applied to general price indices P = eP* A more useful form of PPP is A more useful form of PPP is %Change in e = Inflation – Inflation* For example, if the US inflation rate (annual) is 4% while the annual European inflation rate is 2%, the the dollar should depreciate by 2% over the year. For example, if the US inflation rate (annual) is 4% while the annual European inflation rate is 2%, the the dollar should depreciate by 2% over the year.

PPP and the “Fundamentals” Again, recall that PPP gives the following formula for the nominal exchange rate: Again, recall that PPP gives the following formula for the nominal exchange rate: e = P/P*

PPP and the “Fundamentals” Again, recall that PPP gives the following formula for the nominal exchange rate: Again, recall that PPP gives the following formula for the nominal exchange rate: e = P/P* Further, the quantity theory give the price level as a function of money and output Further, the quantity theory give the price level as a function of money and output P = MV/Y

PPP and the “Fundamentals” Again, recall that PPP gives the following formula for the nominal exchange rate: Again, recall that PPP gives the following formula for the nominal exchange rate: e = P/P* Further, the quantity theory give the price level as a function of money and output Further, the quantity theory give the price level as a function of money and output P = MV/Y Combining the two, Combining the two, e = (V/V*)(M/M*)(Y*/Y) V,M,and Y are exchange rate “fundamentals” V,M,and Y are exchange rate “fundamentals”

PPP and the Real Exchange Rate While the nominal exchange rate is defined as the dollar price of foreign currency, the real exchange rate is defined as the price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods While the nominal exchange rate is defined as the dollar price of foreign currency, the real exchange rate is defined as the price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods q = eP*/P

PPP and the Real Exchange Rate While the nominal exchange rate is defined as the dollar price of foreign currency, the real exchange rate is defined as the price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods While the nominal exchange rate is defined as the dollar price of foreign currency, the real exchange rate is defined as the price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods q = eP*/P PPP implies that the real exchange is always constant (actually, its equal to 1) PPP implies that the real exchange is always constant (actually, its equal to 1)

Interest Rate Parity Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E

Interest Rate Parity Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E Each $1 invested in the US will be worth $1.05 in a year. How about each $ invested in Europe?

Interest Rate Parity Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E Each $1 invested in the US will be worth $1.05 in a year. How about each $1 invested in Europe? $1 = (1/1.15) =.87E.87E(1.07) =.93E.93E ($1.10/E) = $1.02

Interest Rate Parity Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return Interest rate parity is the asset equivalent of PPP. It states that all assets should be expected to earn the same return For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E For example, suppose that the interest rate in the US is 5%, the interest rate in Europe is 7%,, the current exchange rate is $1.15/E and the anticipated exchange rate in a year is $1.10/E Each $1 invested in the US will be worth $1.05 in a year. How about each $1 invested in Europe? $1 = (1/1.15) =.87E.87E(1.07) =.93E.93E ($1.10/E) = $1.02 Even with the higher return in Europe, the 5% appreciation of the dollar makes the US asset a better investment. Therefore, funds will flow to the US.

Interest Rate Parity Interest parity states that exchange rates should be expected to adjust such that assets pay equal returns across countries Interest parity states that exchange rates should be expected to adjust such that assets pay equal returns across countries (1+i) = (1+i*)(e’/e)

Interest Rate Parity Interest parity states that exchange rates should be expected to adjust such that assets pay equal returns across countries Interest parity states that exchange rates should be expected to adjust such that assets pay equal returns across countries (1+i) = (1+i*)(e’/e) A more useful form is A more useful form is i – i* = % change in e For example, if the interest rate in the US is 5% and the interest rate in Japan is 2%, the dollar should depreciate by 3% against the Yen For example, if the interest rate in the US is 5% and the interest rate in Japan is 2%, the dollar should depreciate by 3% against the Yen

Interest Rate Parity Interest parity states that exchange rates should be expected to adjust such that assets pay equal returns across countries Interest parity states that exchange rates should be expected to adjust such that assets pay equal returns across countries (1+i) = (1+i*)(e’/e) A more useful form is A more useful form is i – i* = % change in e For example, if the interest rate in the US is 5% and the interest rate in Japan is 2%, the dollar should depreciate by 3% against the Yen For example, if the interest rate in the US is 5% and the interest rate in Japan is 2%, the dollar should depreciate by 3% against the Yen Interest rate parity fails just as badly as PPP. Interest rate parity fails just as badly as PPP.

Interest Rate Parity & PPP Recall that PPP gives the following: Recall that PPP gives the following: % change in e = Inflation – Inflation*

Interest Rate Parity & PPP Recall that PPP gives the following: Recall that PPP gives the following: % change in e = Inflation – Inflation* Interest Parity gives the following: Interest Parity gives the following: i – i* = % change in e

Interest Rate Parity & PPP Recall that PPP gives the following: Recall that PPP gives the following: % change in e = Inflation – Inflation* Interest Parity gives the following: Interest Parity gives the following: i – i* = % change in e Combining them gives us Combining them gives us i – i* = Inflation – Inflation*

Interest Rate Parity & PPP Recall that PPP gives the following: Recall that PPP gives the following: % change in e = Inflation – Inflation* Interest Parity gives the following: Interest Parity gives the following: i – i* = % change in e Combining them gives us Combining them gives us i – i* = Inflation – Inflation* i – Inflation = i* - Inflation*

Interest Rate Parity & PPP Recall that PPP gives the following: Recall that PPP gives the following: % change in e = Inflation – Inflation* Interest Parity gives the following: Interest Parity gives the following: i – i* = % change in e Combining them gives us Combining them gives us i – i* = Inflation – Inflation* i – Inflation = i* - Inflation* r = r* r = r*

Summary of Classical Exchange Rate Theory Real interest differentials across countries are zero. Real interest differentials across countries are zero. The trade balance is equal to S – (I + (G-T)) at the world interest rate The trade balance is equal to S – (I + (G-T)) at the world interest rate Real exchange rates are constant Real exchange rates are constant Nominal Exchange rates are related to the “fundamentals” Nominal Exchange rates are related to the “fundamentals” e = (V/V*)(M/M*)(Y*/Y) There is no obvious correlation between trade balances, interest rates and exchange rates There is no obvious correlation between trade balances, interest rates and exchange rates

Exchange Rates & the Fundamentals (JPY/USD)

Exchange Rates & the Fundamentals (GBP/USD)

Nominal/Real Exchange Rates

Explaining Deviations from PPP Transportation costs, tariffs, taxes, etc. interfere with LOOP Transportation costs, tariffs, taxes, etc. interfere with LOOP Non-Traded goods Non-Traded goods Changes in Terms of Trade Changes in Terms of Trade Price indices are constructed differently Price indices are constructed differently Fixed prices in the short run (Keynesian Economics) Fixed prices in the short run (Keynesian Economics)

Trading Costs: An Example Suppose that the price of gold in Britain is L 210 while the price of gold in the US is $300 Suppose that the price of gold in Britain is L 210 while the price of gold in the US is $300

Trading Costs: An Example Suppose that the price of gold in Britain is L 210 while the price of gold in the US is $300 Suppose that the price of gold in Britain is L 210 while the price of gold in the US is $300 The LOOP exchange rate (GBP/USD)will be equal to The LOOP exchange rate (GBP/USD)will be equal to e = P*/P = L 210 / $300 = L.7/$

Trading Costs: An Example Suppose that the price of gold in Britain is L 210 while the price of gold in the US is $300 Suppose that the price of gold in Britain is L 210 while the price of gold in the US is $300 The LOOP exchange rate (USD/GBP) will be equal to The LOOP exchange rate (USD/GBP) will be equal to e = P/P* = $300 / L210 = $1.43/L If the exchange rate deviates from.1.43, profits from arbitrage would be If the exchange rate deviates from.1.43, profits from arbitrage would be P – eP* (Buy in GB, sell in US) eP* - P (Buy in US, sell in GB)

Trading Costs: An Example Now, assume a $10 trading cost Now, assume a $10 trading cost Profits from arbitrage would now be Profits from arbitrage would now be P – (eP*+10) (Buy in GB, sell in US) eP* - (P+10) (Buy in US, sell in GB)

Trading Costs: An Example Now, assume a $10 trading cost Now, assume a $10 trading cost Profits from arbitrage would now be Profits from arbitrage would now be P – (eP*+10) (Buy in GB, sell in US) eP* - (P+10) (Buy in US, sell in GB) Solving for the exchange rate gives us a range in which arbitrage is not profitable Solving for the exchange rate gives us a range in which arbitrage is not profitable (P-10)/P* < e < (P+10)/P* 1.38 < e < 1.47

Trading Costs: An Example

Non-Traded Goods: An Example Suppose that in addition to gold, we add theatre tickets. Theatre tickets in the US cost $40 while in Britain, similar tickets cost L 30. Further, assume that the price index is defined (in both Britain and the US) as P =.3(Tickets) +.7(Gold) Suppose that in addition to gold, we add theatre tickets. Theatre tickets in the US cost $40 while in Britain, similar tickets cost L 30. Further, assume that the price index is defined (in both Britain and the US) as P =.3(Tickets) +.7(Gold)

Non-Traded Goods: An Example Suppose that in addition to gold, we add theatre tickets. Theatre tickets in the US cost $40 while in Britain, similar tickets cost L 30. Further, assume that the price index is defined (in both Britain and the US) as P =.3(Tickets) +.7(Gold) Suppose that in addition to gold, we add theatre tickets. Theatre tickets in the US cost $40 while in Britain, similar tickets cost L 30. Further, assume that the price index is defined (in both Britain and the US) as P =.3(Tickets) +.7(Gold) CPI =.3(40) +.7(300) = $222 CPI =.3(40) +.7(300) = $222 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156

Non-Traded Goods: An Example CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI =.3(40) +.7(300) = $222 CPI =.3(40) +.7(300) = $222 Arbitrage will insure the nominal exchange rate will equal Arbitrage will insure the nominal exchange rate will equal E = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L E = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L

Non-Traded Goods: An Example CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI =.3(40) +.7(300) = $222 CPI =.3(40) +.7(300) = $222 Arbitrage will insure the nominal exchange rate will equal Arbitrage will insure the nominal exchange rate will equal e = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L e = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L The real exchange rate equals The real exchange rate equals q = e(CPI*/CPI) = 1.43(156/222) = 1 q = e(CPI*/CPI) = 1.43(156/222) = 1

Non-Traded Goods: An Example Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50.

Non-Traded Goods: An Example Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI =.3(50) +.7(300) = $225 CPI =.3(50) +.7(300) = $225

Non-Traded Goods: An Example Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI =.3(50) +.7(300) = $225 CPI =.3(50) +.7(300) = $225 the nominal exchange rate stays at the nominal exchange rate stays at e = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L e = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L

Non-Traded Goods: An Example Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. Suppose that the price of a theatre ticket in the US increases to $50. CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI* =.3(30) +.7(210) = L156 CPI =.3(50) +.7(300) = $225 CPI =.3(50) +.7(300) = $225 the nominal exchange rate stays at the nominal exchange rate stays at e = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L e = P/P* = 300/210 = $1.43/L The real exchange rate equals The real exchange rate equals q = e(CPI*/CPI) = 1.43(156/225) =.991 (A real appreciation) q = e(CPI*/CPI) = 1.43(156/225) =.991 (A real appreciation)

Relative Prices and Classical Economics Classical theory begins with the real exchange rate (q) Classical theory begins with the real exchange rate (q)

Relative Prices and Classical Economics Classical theory begins with the real exchange rate (q) Classical theory begins with the real exchange rate (q) Given movements of the real exchange rate, the nominal exchange rate evolves according to Given movements of the real exchange rate, the nominal exchange rate evolves according to e = q(Fundamentals) e = q(Fundamentals) = q(V/V*)(M/M*)(Y*/Y) = q(V/V*)(M/M*)(Y*/Y)

Example The US dollar experienced a sharp appreciation during the eighties. The US dollar experienced a sharp appreciation during the eighties.

Example

Example This could be explained by an increase in the relative price of non-tradeables This could be explained by an increase in the relative price of non-tradeables Globalization lowered manufactured goods prices Globalization lowered manufactured goods prices Falling equipment prices (computers) Falling equipment prices (computers) Rising cost of services (healthcare) Rising cost of services (healthcare) This, however, can’t explain the decline in the dollar in the late eighties This, however, can’t explain the decline in the dollar in the late eighties

Real exchange rates and real interest differentials Recall the interest parity condition Recall the interest parity condition (i-i*) = %change in e (i-i*) = %change in e Subtracting inflation from both sides gives us a real interest parity condition Subtracting inflation from both sides gives us a real interest parity condition (r-r*) = %change in q (r-r*) = %change in q

Relative Prices and the Trade Balance (r-r*) = %change in q (r-r*) = %change in q Therefore, a real depreciation (an increase in q) forces a rise in domestic interest rates (to compensate for declining dollar values) Therefore, a real depreciation (an increase in q) forces a rise in domestic interest rates (to compensate for declining dollar values)

Relative Prices and the Trade Balance Higher interest rates increase domestic savings while lowering domestic investment. This improves the trade balance Higher interest rates increase domestic savings while lowering domestic investment. This improves the trade balance

Classical Exchange Rate Theory and Relative Prices Real exchange rates are determined by relative price changes Real exchange rates are determined by relative price changes Nominal Exchange rates are related to the real exchange rate plus the “fundamentals” Nominal Exchange rates are related to the real exchange rate plus the “fundamentals” e = q (V/V*)(M/M*)(Y*/Y) Real interest differentials across countries are positively related to real exchange rate changes Real interest differentials across countries are positively related to real exchange rate changes Real depreciations (appreciations) will improve (worsen) the trade balances. Real depreciations (appreciations) will improve (worsen) the trade balances.