© 2005 Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP. All rights reserved. Some thoughts on predatory pricing in the context of the Article 82 EC review Robert.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Price Planning Ch. 25 ME.
Advertisements

1 ABA 50th Annual Antitrust Law Spring Meeting Beyond Predatory Pricing Mark C. Schechter April 24, 2002.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
The Eighth Annual Trans- Atlantic Antitrust Dialogue Exclusionary Pricing in Article 82 Cases – A U.S. FTC Perspective Alden F. Abbott Associate Director,
Regulating a Monopolist Monopolist choose output q m,whereas the efficient output is q w. Regulation will be needed to avoid the former result. However,
The BT Margin Squeeze Case Paolo Palmigiano Head of Competition Law BT Retail London, 10 December 2004.
Oligopoly Most firms are part of oligopoly or monopolistic competition, with few monopolies or perfect competition. These two market structures are called.
Price-cost Tests v. Raising Rivals’ Costs for Loyalty Programs and its Implication for the Taking of Advantage of Market Power Provisions 2 nd ATE Symposium.
1 REFORM OF ARTICLE 82 EC BIICL, 24 February 2006 Treatment of Rebates Johanne Peyre.
An academic outsider’s view on the Glaxo case Eric Avenel Grenoble Applied Economics Laboratory.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Chapter 10 The Role of Costs in Pricing Decisions.
Article 82 Discussion Paper Luc Peeperkorn Rita Wezenbeek DG Competition, European Commission Rotterdam, 17 March 2006.
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
Examination of the dynamics of perfect markets with the aid of cost and revenue curves. Perfect competition Individual business and industry Market structure.
IGCSE®/O Level Economics
Administration in International Organizations PUBLIC COMPETITION LAW Class V, 3rd Nov 2014 Krzysztof Rokita.
Economics: Principles in Action
Imperfect Competition and Market Power: Core Concepts Defining Industry Boundaries Barriers to Entry Price: The Fourth Decision Variable Price and Output.
Financial performance measures and transfer pricing
The Four Market Models How do businesses decide what price to charge and how much to produce? It depends on the character of its industry.
The Wanadoo case Jérôme Philippe ACE 2007 Conference, Toulouse.
“Equal and open access to the market in terms of economic integration and increased competition ” Astana Forum, 24 May 2013 Presented by Hassan Qaqaya,
Post Danmark: a big step towards a consistent application of a consumer oriented effects-based approach to exclusionary pricing practices Luc Peeperkorn*
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
London 22 Nov 2005 Modernization of Article 82 Lars-Hendrik Röller * Chief Competition Economist European Commission CLA and BIICL Conference on Article.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Chapter 11 Pushing Exports.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
CHAPTER 21 PURE COMPETITION COMPETITION.
Types of Market Structure in the Construction Industry
Competition and Market Power
Chapter 4 Solutions. Exercise 4-5A Since the product- and facility-sustaining costs do not differ between the alternatives, they are not avoidable. The.
Contestable Markets A2 Economics.
Economics RBB 26 JANUARY 2007SIMON BISHOP THE LAW AND ECONOMICS OF LOYALTY REBATES CENTRE FOR COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY, OXFORD UNIVERSITY.
John Hayes 15 May 2008 The 8th Annual Trans-Atlantic Antitrust Dialogue Economic Issues in the Commission’s Case Against Intel.
Dynamic Markets and the Abuse of a Dominant Position Athens, June 1-2, 2007 by Federico Etro University of Milan, Bicocca.
How to assess vertical mergers cast your vote! Miguel de la Mano* Member of the Chief Economist Team DG COMP, European Commission *The views expressed.
Chapter Six Profit Maximization: Seeking Competitive Advantage.
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly Chapter 11.
Monopolistic Competition Topic 7(a). Contents 1. Characteristics of MC 2. Short run profit maximisation 3. Long run equilibrium 4. Assessment of MC 5.
Industrial Economics And antitrust The Tetra Pak II case Silvia Compagnoni Evelyn Doering.
The economics of Article 82 reform Dr Helen Jenkins, Managing Director February 8th 2008.
Contribution. Definition of contribution Contribution is the difference between sales revenue and variable cost Contribution is the difference between.
UNCTAD The interface between competition policy, trade, investment and development Geneva, 23 July 2007 Abuse of Market Power Presentation by: Ursula Ferrari.
1 Federal Network Agency for Electricity, Gas, Telecommunications, Post and Railways Michael Schimmel Price squeeze tests in electronic communications.
Receivables Management For Management Related Notes and Assignments, Visit
Chapter 10 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
Unilateral Exclusionary Conduct – An Analytical Framework Jorge Fagundes 3rd Coloquio - ForoCompetencia Buenos Aires, Argentina – November 2, 2007 Fagundes.
1 Economic Analysis in Competition Law – A Lawyer’s Perspective A. Douglas Melamed March 23, 2009.
Post Danmark II in context
The dominance concept: new wine in old bottles Miguel de la Mano * Member of the Chief Economist’s Office DG COMP, European Commission FTC/DOJ Hearings.
1.4.5 Monopoly and the allocation of resources What is the objective in a game of monopoly? Use your knowledge of economics to explain why a hotel on Old.
SMP and dominance Pál Belényesi Verona 29 November November 2006.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
© Hogan & Hartson LLP. All rights reserved. Monopoly Power: Getting it and keeping it US Perspective Sharis Pozen, Partner ACCE Seminar 13 May 2008.
Article 82 and Structural Remedies After Microsoft International Competition Forum St Gallen May, 2008 Dr Philip Marsden Director and Senior Research.
If the primary determinant of a firm's profitability is the attractiveness of the industry in which it operates, an important secondary determinant.
Article 82 and the courts The burden and standard of proof Kelyn Bacon 24 February 2006.
LECTURE 2 - AGENDA The role of cost information in pricing decisions Pricing in regulated (monopoly) situations Common cost terms used in EU Prof. Teemu.
The Economic Environment of Business – Lecture 5 Competition Policy.
PHILIPPINE COMPETITION ACT
Strategic Management: Environments (know your enemy) Dr David R Moore
African Competition Forum
Transfer Pricing, Evaluating and Managing Performance
23 Pure Competition.
Chapter 8: Selecting an appropriate price level
Lecture 14 Monopolistic competition
Abuse of Dominance Case Studies.
Intel and the future of Article 102 TFEU
Presentation transcript:

© 2005 Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP. All rights reserved. Some thoughts on predatory pricing in the context of the Article 82 EC review Robert O’Donoghue Brussels, June 17, 2005 Global Competition Law Centre Conference, 2005

2 Agenda  Issue #1: what to do with common costs  Issue #2: the role of intent evidence  Issue #3: recoupment  Issue # 4: above cost unconditional price cuts  Issue #5: defences

3 Issue #1: the problem of commons costs  Problem: where two product share common or joint costs, you can calculate total cost, but not average cost  If a firm produces both cars and trucks and has common costs then, while it is possible to identify total cost or variable cost, it is not possible to add together cars and cars and trucks to get an average cost  Real issue in practice, since most firms have common costs  Not clear what the solution is or should be

4 Issue #1: the problem of commons costs  Solution #1: do nothing - focus only on incremental costs and revenue since these guide business decisions  But this can create significant bias against rivals with stand-alone activities  Solution #2: use stand-alone costs.  But wholly inappropriate since higher than dominant firm’s actual costs  Solution #3: allocate costs between operations in some reasonable way.  But well-known that all methods of common cost allocation are problematic

5 Issue #1: the problem of commons costs  Support for common cost allocation: –Ahmed Saeed mentions fully allocated cost test –Postal Notice also mentions need to allocate costs between competitive and non-competitive operations  Support for incremental costs only approach –Deutsche Post – Commission applied incremental costs test (LRIC) to competitive market –But strong suggestion that this was because of legal obligation to offer universal service mail –Firm without legal obligation could take shut down decision –Absent legal obligation, LRIC approach could offer dominant firm too much freedom to decide which of its costs in the competitive market were incremental and which were not

6 Issue #1: the problem of commons costs  Resolving the common cost “problem” –LRIC generally to be preferred, since it most closely accords with actual business decisions –Common cost allocation only potentially relevant where common costs are “substantial” –If so, allocation should be subject to test of “reasonableness.” –If “reasonable,” allocate costs. Various methods of common cost allocation: (1) Ramsey pricing; (2) equal proportionate mark up; (3) in proportion to turnover; (4) arm’s length negotiation. (2) and (3) the most practical, though flawed. –Any doubt, benefit goes to defendant

7 Issue # 2: the role of intent evidence  Second AKZO rule: prices above AVC but below ATC abusive where part of a plan to eliminate a competitor.  Wanadoo: first major case in which evidence of (mainly subjective) intent played a role  “Plan to preempt the market by stealing the march on competitors.” (para. 111); “regardless of the short-term financial disadvantage” (para. 135); serious internal doubts about future economic viability of losses (para. 139)  Commission draws a distinction between formal presentations to management and informal remarks made to or by sales staff, attaching a higher value to the former.  Documents must also show such intent on the part of senior staff capable of having a material influence on company policy.  Focus on the totality of evidence, not isolated statements

8 Issue # 2: the role of intent evidence  Significant problems with subjective intent evidence  Some Wanadoo statements very similar to vigorous competition statements.  Dangerous in particular because prices above AVC are rational, at least in the short-term  Better to look at more objective evidence of intent: whether the strategy was incrementally profitable or not  Avoidable cost test useful: would it have been cheaper to stay in business or shut down?  Prices that pass both the AVC and average avoidable cost tests should conclusively show an absence of predatory behaviour

9 Issue #3: recoupment  Many economists argue that, absent proof of recoupment, below cost prices are a net boon for consumers  Status of recoupment under Article 82 not clear: –Rejected, on the facts, in Tetra Pak II –Wanadoo – rejected recoupment as a formal requirement but went on to consider ability to recoup in any event –Issue was whether “the obstacles to entry guarantee the dominant undertaking the maintenance in the long term of a large degree of market concentration in its favour” (para. 337) –Commission identified a number of strategic barriers: (1) disincentives to switching subscribers on the part of existing customers; (2) high costs of entering and acquiring critical size in the broadband market (e.g., fixed costs, advertising costs); (3) self-building of the upstream infrastructure needed for a broadband network was not viable; and (4) Wanadoo was well on its way to restoring profitable margins, whereas new entrants were not.

10 Issue #3: recoupment  Commission’s approach reasonable on the whole  Some problems with recoupment in practice: –Perverse results: lower the price cut, the harder to recoup –Speculation as to future market conditions difficult: whoever bears the burden will likely lose –Anti-competitive effects possible absent full recoupment, e.g., maintaining monopoly, reputation effects, oligopoly effects –Not unreasonable in law to punish conduct that ought to be self-deterring  Remember: recoupment under U.S. law rooted in case where the firm was not already dominant (Brooke Group oligopoly)  Existing dominance raises reasonable inference of successful predation: let defendant rebut it

11 Issue # 4: above cost unconditional prices  Surprisingly, many more cases on abusive above-cost unconditional prices than below-cost (Hilti, Irish Sugar, CEWAL)  Economic case for anti-competitive effect of such price cuts can be made, in theory (see Vickers and Armstrong (1993))  Not clear in practice whether restrictions on such price cuts enhance competition overall –Unnecessary for less efficient firms who would have entered absent such a restriction –Unnecessary for more efficient firms who would have entered anyway –No point in protecting firms who are less efficient, but become as efficient over time: capital markets should fund such firms anyway –No point in protecting less efficient firms who would remain so decreases welfare, since competition would eliminate them anyway  In any event, implementation difficulties render a general restriction unworkable

12 Issue #4: above cost unconditional prices  Strong case for treating all above cost unconditional discounts as lawful, due mainly to implementation issues  If review under Article 82 is to be kept, need to articulate legal basis: –Exclusionary “intent” cannot be the rule, since this is also the second AKZO rule –“Superdominance” impossible to define outside of a monopoly and would confuse the law further –Enforcement, if any, should be confined to cases of several, cumulative abuses, i.e., a multi-layered exclusionary strategy

13 Issue #5: defences  Recent economic work shows that pricing below cost may have legitimate explanation (Brodley et al (2000))  But serious disconnect between theory that certain defences are admissible and actual acceptance  Meeting competition. Based on notion that dominant firms can compete and should not sit idly by where there is competition. Short-run profit maximising response.  Prices below AVC. Meeting competition defence initially rejected by Areeda & Turner. But accepted in Berlingske Gratisaviser (2002) where dominant firm matched, but did not undercut, rival’s price. Wanadoo ambiguous on the issue.

14 Issue #5: defences  Prices above AVC but below ATC. Meeting competition in principle more likely to apply. Issue turns on intent, but better to apply objective test based on avoidable cost. Dominant firm should be allowed to undercut and not only match.  Prices above ATC. Should be conclusively legal – no need for defence  Relevance of selective pricing –Treated as exacerbating factor in the case law, presumably because it makes the losses less costly and more sustainable –Seems odd to say that firm could avoid liability by incurring more widespread losses –Better view is that selective pricing does not in itself evidence predatory intent, but, when coupled with other evidence of exclusionary intent, such an inference may be appropriate and the meeting competition defence therefore inapplicable

15 Issue #5: defences  Other defences deserve serious consideration –Market-expanding efficiencies –Promotional offers –Loss-leading –Loss-minimising –Excess capacity –Mistake –Obsolescent goods