1 G601, IO I Eric Rasmusen, 27 September 2006 (revised after class) RISK.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
BUY ONE, GET ONE FREE! BUY THREE PRODUCTS, GET THE THIRD FREE!! TRIPLE POINTS THIS WEEK-END ONLY!!! Whats our favourite???
Advertisements

Chapter 13 Learning Objectives
34 Financial Economics McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Choices Involving Risk
1 Coase, Theory of the Firm, Tirole chapter 0 Eric Rasmusen, G604, Tirole-Coasle, size of firms, 14 November,
1 G601, IO I Eric Rasmusen, 13 September 2006 Accounting Data, and Finance II This is for one 75 minute session.
1 G601, IO I Eric Rasmusen, 13 September 2006 Accounting and Data I This is for one 75 minute session.
1 G601, IO I Eric Rasmusen, 5 September mixed, Cournot This is for one 75 minute session on the chapter. The big idea is mixing.
1 Coase, Theory of the Firm, Tirole chapter 0 Eric Rasmusen, G604, Tirole-Coasle, size of firms, march 28, 2006.
1 G601, IO I Eric Rasmusen, 31 August – Info This is for one 75 minute session on the chapter. The big idea is bayesian equilibrium.
6 - 1 Copyright © 2002 by Harcourt, Inc All rights reserved. CHAPTER 6 Risk and Return: The Basics Basic return concepts Basic risk concepts Stand-alone.
© Family Economics & Financial Education – Revised November 2004 – Saving Unit – Rule of 72 Funded by a grant from Take Charge America, Inc. to the Norton.
From risk to opportunity Lecture 11 John Hey and Carmen Pasca.
Slides 8a: Introduction
Risk, Return, and the Time Value of Money
Chapter Outline 7.1 Risk Aversion and Demand for Insurance by Individuals The Effects of Insurance on Wealth Risk Aversion Other Factors Affecting an Individual’s.
Unit 11 Insurance North Carolina Driver and Traffic Safety Education Association 1 INSURANCE UNIT 11.
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Risk, Uncertainty, and Information.
Choose to Save Advanced Level.
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
Government Policies That Alter the Private Market Outcome
Financial Education and Career Planning Review Quiz Unit-4 Credit and Credit Cards.
Key Concepts and Skills
Analyzing Transactions
Your boss asks… How many of these things do we have to sell before we start making money? Use your arrow keys to navigate the slides.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Section 5.3: Inflation and the Consumer Price Index.
Chapter 16 Goodness-of-Fit Tests and Contingency Tables
1 Money Utility and wealth. 2 Example Consider a stock investment for 5000 which could increase or decrease by +/ Let current wealth be C An investor.
1 The Time Value of Money Learning Module. 2 The Time Value of Money Would you prefer to have $1 million now or $1 million 10 years from now? Of course,
Activity 1………………Saving vs. Investing Activity 2……….….Saving for a Rainy Day Activity 3…………………… = Saving Activity 4…..Investing for the Long Term.
The Time Value of Money.
1 Time is Money: Personal Finance Applications of the Time Value of Money Barbara ONeill, Ph.D, CFP.
Time Value of Money Time value of money: $1 received today is not the same as $1 received in the future. How do we equate cash flows received or paid at.
Choice under Uncertainty. Introduction Many choices made by consumers take place under conditions of uncertainty Therefore involves an element of risk.
A Key to Economic Analysis
Chapter 6 Trade-Off Between Risk & Return
Risk and Return Learning Module.
The Time Value of Money Learning Module.
Chapter Organisation 6.1 Bond Valuation 6.2 Common Stock Valuation
Chapter 5: Time Value of Money: The Basic Concepts
Financial Sector Review Questions
1 Lesson Dividing with Integers. 2 Lesson Dividing with Integers California Standard: Number Sense 2.3 Solve addition, subtraction, multiplication,
11-1 CHAPTER 11 The Basics of Capital Budgeting Should we build this plant?
FIRM BEHAVIOR AND THE ORGANIZATION OF INDUSTRY
Theories of investor preferences Signaling effects Residual model
Decision Rules. Decision Theory In the final part of the course we’ve been studying decision theory, the science of how to make rational decisions. So.
5.1 Suppose a person must accept one of three bets:
Introduction: Thinking Like an Economist 1 CHAPTER The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand The theory of economics must begin.
Key Concepts and Skills
Chapter 12 Uncertainty Consider two lotteries L 1 : 500,000 (1) L 1 ’: 2,500,000 (0.1), 500,000 (0.89), 0 (0.01) Which one would you choose? Another two.
Lecture 4 on Individual Optimization Risk Aversion
Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior
Last Day Utility Analysis. Today Utility Analysis (cont’d) International Diversification.
Extensions to Consumer theory Inter-temporal choice Uncertainty Revealed preferences.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
The Pricing of Risky Financial Assets Risk and Return.
Decision-making under uncertainty. Introduction Definition of risk Attitudes toward risk Avoiding risk: Diversification Insurance.
Chapter The Basic Tools of Finance 14. Present Value: Measuring the Time Value of Money Finance – Studies how people make decisions regarding Allocation.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University The Basic Tools of Finance 1 © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.
1 Overview of Risk and Return Timothy R. Mayes, Ph.D. FIN 3300: Chapter 8.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 27 The Basic Tools of Finance.
UNDERSTANDING RISK AND RETURN CHAPTER TWO Practical Investment Management Robert A. Strong.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
Chapter 5 Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.Chapter 52 Q: Value of Stock Investment in offshore drilling exploration: Two.
Chapter 5 Choice Under Uncertainty. Chapter 5Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Describing Risk Preferences Toward Risk Reducing Risk The Demand for Risky.
Decision theory under uncertainty
Chapter Seventeen Uncertainty. © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Topics  Degree of Risk.  Decision Making Under Uncertainty.
On Investor Behavior Objective Define and discuss the concept of rational behavior.
Chapter The Basic Tools of Finance 27. Present Value: Measuring the Time Value of Money Finance – Studies how people make decisions regarding Allocation.
Presentation transcript:

1 G601, IO I Eric Rasmusen, 27 September 2006 (revised after class) RISK

2 Readings 26 September, Tuesday. Risk I have posted some notes on the math of defining risk aversion. My new notes are on my weblog and at risk.htm. I have other weblog entries that I might talk about on prospect-theory- and-loss-aversion, on Gollier's table-to-check-your-own-level of risk aversion, and on Knightian-risk-and-uncertainty discussed using two- card-bets. For reference: "When Does Extra Risk Strictly Increase the Value of Options?" Eric Rasmusen, forthcoming in The Review of Financial Studies.notes on my weblog risk.htm.prospect-theory- and-loss-aversionGollier's table-to-check-your-own-level of risk aversion, Knightian-risk-and-uncertainty discussed using two- card-bets."When Does Extra Risk Strictly Increase the Value of Options?" Due: Problem Set 3: 4.5, 5.4, 6.3, and 6.4. Answers are (or will be) here.here.

3 Handouts Hand in Problem Set 3: 4.5, 5.4, 6.3, and 6.4.

4 The idea of risk aversion is that people like to keep their consumption at a steady level rather than up and down. They prefer to consume $50,000 per year rather than $10,000 one year and $90,000 the next. The conventional way to represent this is with a strictly concave utility function, such as (A) U = log(C) If the utility function is concave like this, then from any starting point a loss of $1 hurts more than a gain of $1 helps.

5 Caring about Probabilities of Probabilities Suppose Jack might earn $100, $200, $300, or $400, with equal probabilities, an expected wealth of $250. His information partition is (100,200,300,400)-- he can't rule out anything. Jack is very risk averse, so his utilities from known wealths are U(100) = 0 - e U(200) = e U(300) = e U(400) = e, where e is the number of hours he works painting a house.

6 The Decision Tom offers to tell Jack whether his wealth will either low or high, but not the precise level, if in exchange Jack will spend 2 hours painting Tom's house. Thus, Jack can get the information partition (100,200), (300,400). Should he accept?

7 Expected Utility Calculations Originally, Jacks expected utility is.25(0) +.25(100) +.25(120) +.25 (128) = 81 If he pays the 2 hours, his expected utility is [.5U(100)+.5 U(200) ]+.5[.5U(300)+.5 U(400) ] which equals U(100) +.25 U(200).25U(300) +.25 U(400) which equals (0) +.25(100) +.25(120) +.25 (128) = = 79.

8 Reducing Risk Resolving subjective uncertainty in beliefs is different from reducing risk. Suppose Jack could pay 2 hours to change the probability distribution to (.5 probability of $200,.5 probability of $300) His expected utility would be (100) +.5 (120) = = 108 (better than 81) But that is not just a change in his beliefs (though they would change too). It is a change in the probabilities of various amounts of cash he might receive. He has ruled out getting a mere $100.

9 Anxiety Another way to look at all this is that using Expected Utility Theory, Jack cares only about end states, not about his beliefs along the way. His utility from getting $400 on Friday is entirely pleasure that he gets on Friday when he receives the cash (or, better, when he spends the cash). He get no pleasure on Tuesday, Wednesday, or Thursday from anticipating his happiness on Friday. We could model anxiety earlier in the week about the uncertainty, but it would take a different model. We could, in the example earlier, say that today, before Jack knows his future wealth, he gets immediate utility of -20*(4-N) if his information partition has N information sets. Then, it would make sense for Jack to pay 20 hours of labor to increase N from 1 to 2, because it would cost 2 in utility and gain 20.

10 Anxiety In addition to the Friday utilities above, Jack might have Tuesday utility of V(100) = -400 V(200) = 100 V(300) = 120 V(400) = 126 from perfect information on Tuesday, and from coarser info: V(100,200) = -300 V(300,400) = 122 V(100,200,300,400) = 0 The expected utility gain as a result of getting better information would then be 0 +.5(-300) +.5 (122) = = -91.

11 LOSS AVERSION Suppose Joe makes $500/month payments for his car. If he makes $10/month less, he is in trouble. If he makes $20/month less, that isn't much worse. Hence, his behavior will seem to violate the assumption of concave utility. Suppose he has a 5% chance of losing $10 and a 5% chance of losing $20. He would prefer to have a 1% chance of losing $10 and an 8% chance of losing $20. He is positively risk loving! On the other hand, suppose this person starts to make $10/month more In the long run, when his car needs replacing, he will smoothly change to $510/month. (here, use my old weblog entry on prospect theory)

12 Diversification reduces risk Apex stock: $0 or $3 with equal probability Brydox stock: $0 or $3 with equal probability A share of stock costs $1. You have $6 to invest. (X) If you invest in 6 shares of Brydox, your end wealth is either $0 or $18, an expected value of $9. (Y) If you invest in 3 shares of Apex and 3 of Brydox, your end wealth is either $0, $9, $9, or $18, with equal probabilities, an expected value of $9. The diversified strategy is less risky. Thus, if there are lots of independent assets, you should spread your investment across all of them. The risk from any 1 company's behavior would be trivial. Thus, you would be happy for that company to ignore risk and simply to maximize its expected value.

13 Combination of risk does not reduce risk: Only division does Suppose you could invest in the stock of Brydox, which yields either $0 or $3 with equal probability, or the stock of Brydox, which also yields either $0 or $3 with equal probability, but with independent probability. A share of stock costs $1, and you have $6 to invest. All this is the same as in my previous example. Now, however, you are thinking of investing either (1) $3 in Apex and $3 in cash, OR (2) $3 in Apex and $3 in Brydox. Which is less risky? If you invest in both companies, will the risks tend to cancel out?

14 The Fallacy of Large Numbers (A) One strategy is to invest $3 in Apex and $3 in cash. This will have a return of $3 or $12, with equal probability. the expected return will be $7.50. (B) The other strategy is to invest $3 in Apex and $3 in Brydox. This will have a return of $0, $9, $9, or $18, with equal probabilities, as we found earlier. The expected return will be $9. If you were risk neutral or slightly risk averse, you'd choose strategy (B) But suppose your utility function was the following strictly concave function: U = log(C) if C greater than 2 U = log (C) if C less than or equal to 2 That's discontinuous, but there's nothing wrong with that. The main thing for this person is to avoid consumption of less than 2. Thus, he would prefer strategy (A). (Doug Diamond, Paul Samuelson)

15 Applications Insurance companies dont work by adding up risks that cancel out. They work by dividing risk among lots of policyholders or stockholders. Diversification across time is a misleading idea. It is not true that its safe to invest in stocks so long as you keep your money in for 50 years, because historically no 50-year period has ever had negative stock returns. Wed expect that over 50 years the return would be very close to the average per decade– say, a 90% chance of that. But there would be some chance of a truly horrendous loss from being unlucky in each of those 50 years. And were not likely to observe that bad luck in many 50-year periods– a peso problem. This is also related to the Gamblers Ruin paradox that if you keep taking gambles with better than fair returns, youll go bankrupt eventually with probability one.

16 Housing as Investment Suppose I have $40,000 per year in labor income and $100,000 in wealth. This year, I have two choices. A.I could invest $100,000 in bonds for a safe 10% return, and pay $10,000 in rent for a house. B. I could invest $100,000 in a house and not pay rent. House prices swing wildly, between $80,000 and $120,000, with an expected future price of $100,000.

17

18 Course Website A link to the course website