Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment 45-976 Professor Robert A. Miller Mini 3, 2005-2006.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Introduction to Game Theory
Advertisements

Ultimatum Game Two players bargain (anonymously) to divide a fixed amount between them. P1 (proposer) offers a division of the “pie” P2 (responder) decides.
How are reputations established? In this lecture we explore three ways, through small changes in the payoffs (such as limited warranties), affecting the.
Chapter 11.  Monopolistic competition is a market structure in which:  There are a large number of firms  The products produced by the different firms.
Games With No Pure Strategy Nash Equilibrium Player 2 Player
Chapter 14 Infinite Horizon 1.Markov Games 2.Markov Solutions 3.Infinite Horizon Repeated Games 4.Trigger Strategy Solutions 5.Investing in Strategic Capital.
Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Fehr and Falk Wage Rigidity in a Competitive Incomplete Contract Market Economics 328 Spring 2005.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 20/1 Chapter 20 Asymmetric Information and Market Behaviour.
Lecture 2A Strategic form games
Game Theory “Necessity never made a good bargain.” - Benjamin Franklin Mike Shor Lecture 13.
1 Unless otherwise noted, the content of this course material is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution – Non-Commercial 3.0 License.
Game Theory The study of rational behavior among interdependent agents Agents have a common interest to make the pie as large as possible, but Agents have.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Chapter 16 Negotiation 1.Costly Agreements 2.Ultimatum game with Incomplete Information 3.Counteroffers with Incomplete Information 4.The revelation principle.
Chapter 12 Choices Involving Strategy McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Review Midterm3/21 3/7.
Developing Principles in Bargaining. Motivation Consider a purely distributive bargaining situation where impasse is costly to both sides How should we.
1 Section 2d Game theory Game theory is a way of thinking about situations where there is interaction between individuals or institutions. The parties.
Two-Stage Games APEC 8205: Applied Game Theory Fall 2007.
Communication Networks A Second Course Jean Walrand Department of EECS University of California at Berkeley.
Screening and Signaling Edition 7: Chapter 12, pages Edition 6: Chapter 12, pages
Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
Introduction to Game Theory
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Asymmetric Information
Reading Osborne, Chapters 5, 6, 7.1., 7.2, 7.7 Learning outcomes
Chapter 15 Bargaining with Complete Information 1.Scope and Scale of Bargaining 2.Ultimatum Game 3.Multiple rounds 4.Multilateral bargaining 5.Matching.
Our final lecture analyzes optimal contracting in situations when the principal writing the contract has less information than the agent who accepts or.
Chapter 12 Choices Involving Strategy Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
A Game-Theoretic Approach to Strategic Behavior. Chapter Outline ©2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All Rights Reserved. 2 The Prisoner’s Dilemma: An Introduction.
PART FOUR Resource Markets
A limit order market is a real world institution for characterizing the financial sector, and it is also a paradigm for describing trading mechanisms more.
Lecture 2 in Contracts Employment Contracts This lecture studies how those who create and administer organizations design the incentives and institutional.
Auction and Markets Professor Robert A. Miller January 2010 Teaching assistant:Hao Xue
Bargaining Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want …; and.
Lecture 2 An Introduction to Contracts This lecture completes our discussion of bargaining by showing what happens when there is incomplete information.
How are reputations established? In this lecture we explore three ways, through small changes in the payoffs (such as limited warranties), affecting the.
Dynamic Games & The Extensive Form
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
This lecture introduces a second principle for solving games with only singleton information sets, perfect information games. Examples of these games are.
Lecture 7 Course Summary The tools of strategy provide guiding principles that that should help determine the extent and nature of your professional interactions.
Extensive Games with Imperfect Information
Lecture 5A Mixed Strategies and Multiplicity Not every game has a pure strategy Nash equilibrium, and some games have more than one. This lecture shows.
제 10 장 게임이론 Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Lecture 5B Complete Information Games This lecture analyzes complete information games, before turning to a discussion of Home Depot.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
This lecture analyzes how well competitive equilibrium predicts industry outcomes as a function the of the production technology, the number of firms and.
Lecture 1 on Bargaining Setting the Agenda This lecture focuses on the well known problem of how to split the gains from trade or, more generally, mutual.
13-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Chapter 6 Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Chapter 16 Oligopoly and Game Theory. “Game theory is the study of how people behave in strategic situations. By ‘strategic’ we mean a situation in which.
Bargaining games Econ 414. General bargaining games A common application of repeated games is to examine situations of two or more parties bargaining.
By: Donté Howell Game Theory in Sports. What is Game Theory? It is a tool used to analyze strategic behavior and trying to maximize his/her payoff of.
Lecture 4 on Auctions Multiunit Auctions We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. CHAPTER EIGHT BARGAINING Once a union is organized by a group of employees.
Lecture V: Bargaining Recommended Reading: Dixit & Skeath, Chapter 17 Osborne, Chapter 6.1, 16 Powell, In the Shadow of Power, Ch. 3.
Lecture 5 Bargaining This lecture focuses on the well known problem of how to split the gains from trade or, more generally, mutual interaction when the.
Management support systems II
THE ECONOMY: THE CORE PROJECT
Lecture 10 Coordination and Reputation
Strategic Corporate Management
Lecture 4 Bargaining and Contracts
Presentation transcript:

Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment Professor Robert A. Miller Mini 3,

Course website The course website is: Website: At the website I shall post: the course syllabus power points slide lecture notes games you can download handouts related to the projects

Textbook Robert A. Miller and Vesna Prasnikar, “Strategic Play” Stanford University Press (forthcoming) A draft manuscript is available at: We shall focus on upon material found in Chapters 11 through 15 and 1 through 3.

Course objectives This course will help you to: 1. Recognize opportunities in bargaining and strategic investment. (Describe the problem and model it.) 2. Analyze each opportunity to assess its value, and how that value is attained. (Solve the model and simulate it.) 3. Persuade your colleagues to follow your advice. (Analyze the results and report them.)

Lecture 1 Bargaining with complete information This lecture focuses on the well known problem of how to split the gains from trade or, more generally, mutual interaction when the objectives of the bargaining parties diverge. In this lecture we avoid the complications of asymmetrically informed agents.

Resolving conflict Bargaining is one way of resolving a conflict between two or more parties, chosen when all parties view it more favorably relative to the alternatives. Alternative means include: 1. Capitulation 2. Predation and expropriation 3. Warfare and destruction Bargaining also has these elements in it.

Examples of bargaining situations Examples of bargaining situations include: 1. Unions bargain with their employers about wages and working conditions. 2. Professionals negotiate their employment or work contracts when changing jobs. 3. Builders and their clients bargain over the nature and extent of the work to reach a work contract. 4. Pre nuptial agreements are written by partners betrothed to be married. 5. No fault divorce law facilitates bargaining over the division of assets amongst divorcing partners.

Agenda for the lecture In today’s session we: 1. begin with some general remarks about bargaining and the importance of unions 2. analyze the (two person) ultimatum game 3. extend the game to treat repeated offers 4. show what happens as we change the number of bargaining parties 5. broaden the discussion to assignment problems where players match with each other 6. turn to bargaining games where the players have incomplete information 7. discuss the role of signaling in such games.

Unions Unions warrant special mention in discussions of bargaining and industrial relations. They are defined as a continuous associations of wage earners for the purpose of maintaining or improving their remuneration and the conditions of their working lives. In the first half of the 20 th century union membership grew from almost nothing to 35% of the labor force, only to decline to less that 15% at the turn of the millennium.

How their composition has changed Hidden within these gross trends are three composition effects worth mentioning : 1. Employment in the government sector increased from 5% in the early part of the 20 th century to 15% in the 1980s, and then stabilized. Union membership in this sector jumped from about 10% to about 40% between 1960 and Employment in agriculture declined from 20% to 3% in the same period. This sector was not unionized at the turn of the 20 th century. 3. Unionization in the nonagricultural private sector has reflected the aggregate trend, declining to about 10% of the workforce down from 35%.

Cross sectional characteristics Within the U.S. membership is highest in the industrial belt connecting New York with Chicago though Pittsburgh and Detroit (20 – 30%), lower in upper New England and the west (10 – 20%), and lowest in the South and Southwest (10% or less). Males are 50% more likely to be union members than females, mainly reflecting their occupational choices. Union membership differs greatly across countries: Canada35% France 12% Sweden 85% United Kingdom 40%

Industrial breakdown and strikes Strikes are dramatic and newsworthy, but they are also quite rare: Less than 5% of union members go on strike within a typical work year. Less than 1% of potential working hours of union members are lost from strikes, before accounting for compensating overtime. About 90% of all collective agreements are renewed without a strike, but the threat of a strike affects more than 10%.

Three dimensions of bargaining We shall focus on three dimensions of bargaining: 1. How many parties are involved, and what is being traded or shared? 2. What are the bargaining rules and/or how do the parties communicate their messages to each other? 3. How much information do the bargaining parties have about their partners? Answering these questions helps us to predict the outcome of the negotiations.

Ultimatum games We begin with one of the simplest bargaining games for 2 or more players. One player is designated the proposer, the others are called responders. The proposer makes a proposal. If enough responders agree to this proposal, then it is accepted and implemented. Otherwise the proposal is rejected, and a default plan is implemented instead.

2 player ultimatum games We consider the problem of splitting a dollar between two players, and investigate three versions of it: 1. The proposer offers anything between 0 and 1, and the responder either accepts or rejects the offer. 2. The proposer makes an offer, and the responder either accepts or rejects the offer, without knowing exactly what the proposer receives. 3. The proposer selects an offer, and the responder simultaneously selects a reservation value. If the reservation value is less than the offer, then the responder receives the offer, but only in that case.

Solution The game theoretic solution is the same in all three cases. Does the experimental evidence support that hypothesis? The solution is for the proposer to extract (almost) all the surplus, and for the responder to accept the proposal. Observe the same outcome would occur if, right at the outset, the responder had capitulated, or if the proposer had expropriated the whole surplus.

Two rounds of bargaining Suppose that a responder has a richer message space than simply accepting or rejecting the initial proposal. After an initial proposal is made, we now assume: 1. The responder may accept the proposal, or with probability p, make a counter offer. 2. If the initial offer is rejected, the game ends with probability 1 – p. 3. If a counter offer is made, the original proposer either accepts or rejects it. 4. The game ends when an offer is accepted, but if both offers are rejected, no transaction takes place.

Solution to a 2 round bargaining game In the final period the second player recognizes that the first will accept any final strictly positive offer, no matter how small. Therefore the second player reject any offer with a share less than p in the total gains from trade. The first player anticipates the response of the second player to his initial proposal. Accordingly the first player offers the second player proportion p, which is accepted.

A finite round bargaining game This game can be extended to a finite number of rounds, where two players alternate between making proposals to each other. Suppose there are T rounds. If the proposal in round t < T is rejected, the bargaining continues for another round with probability p, where 0 < p < 1. In that case the player who has just rejected the most recent proposal makes a counter offer. If T proposals are rejected, the bargaining ends. If no agreement is reached, both players receive nothing. If an agreement is reached, the payoffs reflect the terms of the agreement.

Sub-game perfection If the game reaches round T - K without reaching an agreement, the player proposing at that time will treat the last K rounds as a K round game in which he leads off with the first proposal. Therefore the amount a player would initially offer the other in a K round game, is identical to the amount he would offer if there are K rounds to go in T > K round game and it was his turn.

Solution to finite round bargaining game One can show using the principle of mathematical induction that the value of making the first offer in a T round alternating offer bargaining is: v T = 1 – p + p 2 –... + p T = (1 + p T )/(1 + p) where T is an odd number. Observe that as T diverges, v T converges to: v T = 1 /(1 + p)

Infinite horizon We now directly investigate the solution of the infinite horizon alternating offer bargaining game. Let v denote the value of the game to the proposer in an infinite horizon game. Then the value of the game to the responder is at least pv, since he will be the proposer next period if he rejects the current offer, and there is another offer round. The proposer can therefore attain a payoff of: v = 1 – pv => v = 1/(1+p) which is the limit of the finite horizon game payoff.

Alternatives to taking turns Bargaining parties do not always take turns. We now explore two alternatives: 1. Only one player is empowered to make offers, and the other can simply respond by accepting or rejecting it. 2. Each period in a finite round game one party is selected at random to make an offer.

When only one player makes offers In this case, the proposer makes an offer in the second round, if his first round offer is rejected. The solution reverts to the canonical one period solution. This simply demonstrates that the rules about who can make an offer affects the outcome a lot.

When the order is random Suppose there is an equal chance of being the proposer in each period. We first consider a 2 round game, and then an infinite horizon game. As before p denote the probability of continuing negotiations if no agreement is reach at the end of the first round.

Solution to 2 round random offer game If the first round proposal is rejected, then the expected payoff to both parties is p/2. The first round proposer can therefore attain a payoff of: v = 1 – p/2

Solution to infinite horizon random offer game If the first round proposal is rejected, then the expected payoff to both parties is pv/2. The first round proposer can therefore attain a payoff of: v = 1 – pv/2 => 2v = 2 – pv => v = 2/(2 + p) Note that this is identical to the infinitely repeated game for half the continuation probability. These examples together demonstrate that the number of offers is not the only determinant of the bargaining outcome.

Multiplayer ultimatum games We now increase the number of players to N > 2. Each player is initially allocated a random endowment, which everyone observes. The proposer proposes a system of taxes and subsidies to everyone. If at least J < N –1 of the responders accept the proposal, then the tax subsidy system is put in place. Otherwise the resources are not reallocated, and the players consume their initial endowments.

Solution to multiplayer ultimatum game Rank the endowments from the poorest responder to the richest one. Let w n denote the endowment of the n th poorest responder. The proposer offers the J poorest responders their initial endowment (or very little more) and then expropriate the entire wealth of the N – J remaining responders. In equilibrium the J poorest responders accept the proposal, the remaining responders reject the proposal, and it is implemented.

Another multiplayer ultimatum game Now suppose there are 2 proposers and one responder. The proposers make simultaneous offers to the responder. Then the responder accepts at most one proposal. If a proposal is rejected, the proposer receives nothing. If a proposal is accepted, the proposer and the responder receive the allocation specified in the terms of the proposal. If both proposals are rejected, nobody receives anything.

The solution to this game If a proposer makes an offer that does not give the entire surplus to the responder, then the other proposer could make a slightly more attractive offer. Therefore the solution to this bargaining game is for both proposers to offer the entire gains from trade to the responder, and for the responder to pick either one.

Heterogeneous valuations As before, there are 2 proposers and one responder, the proposers make simultaneous offers to the responder, the responder accepts at most one proposal. Also as before if a proposal is rejected, the proposer receives nothing. If a proposal is accepted, the proposer and the responder receive the allocation specified in the terms of the proposal. If both proposals are rejected, nobody receives anything. But let us now suppose that the proposers have different valuations for the item, say v 1 and v 2 respectively, where v 1 < v 2.

Solving heterogeneous valuations game It is not a best response of either proposer to offer less than the other proposer if the other proposer is offering less than both valuations. Furthermore offering more than your valuation is weakly dominated by bidding less than your valuation. Consequently the first proposer offers v 1 or less. Therefore the solution of this game is for the second proposer to offer (marginally more than) v 1 and for the responder to always accept the offer of the second proposer.

Multilateral exchange In all our previous examples, there is at most one transaction. In such games if more than two players were involved, they competed with each other for the right to be one of the trading partners. We now suppose there are opportunities on both sides of the trading mechanism to form a partnership with one of a number of different players. If the prospective partners were identical, then perhaps a market would form. (But that’s !)

Examples of assignment problems We now explore an intermediate case. No two prospective bargaining partners are alike, but matching any two partners from either side of the market might be more productive than not matching them at all. For example: 1.How are a pool of MBA graduates assigned to companies as employees? 2.Who gets tenure at at what university? 3.How are partners matched up across different law firms? 4.How are partners paired for marriage and parenting?

A multilateral bargaining game We consider a bargaining game where a fraction of the players, called publishers, offers royalties to another set of players, called authors, to publish their manuscripts. Each author has only one manuscript, so can can accept at most one offer. Each publisher can only handle one manuscript, but can make multiple offers. If more than one offer is accepted, the publisher may select any one of the accepted offers

Valuing job matches Publishers are not a perfect substitutes. Authors are not identical either. Each publisher and each author is assigned a quality index, denoted respectively by p i and a j for the i th publisher and j th author. In this lecture we suppose the value of forming a match between the i th publisher and j th author, denoted v ij is the product of the two index values of publisher and the author. That is v ij = p i a j

The solution One can show that the best publishers match up with the best authors. This is called positive sorting. It arises because the quality of manuscripts and the reputation of publishers are production compliments. The royalty rate to authors increases with their index. Likewise the net profits to publishers is increasing in their index.

Bargaining with full information Two striking features characterize all the solutions of the bargaining games that we have played so far: 1. An agreement is always reached. 2. Negotiations end after one round. This occurs because nothing is learned from continuing negotiations, yet a cost is sustained because the opportunity to reach an agreement is put at risk from delaying it. Next week we explore the implications of relaxing these two assumptions.