HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg 2005 1 4. Mergers and Acquisitions Mergers are usually categorized by closeness of markets that firms operate in Horizontal.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 12: Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition
Advertisements

Perfect Competition 12.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western What’s Important in Chapter 15 Sources of Monopolies (= Price Makers = Market.
Strategic Pricing: Theory, Practice and Policy Professor John W. Mayo
Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - What is the old empirical IO? The old empirical IO refers to studies that.
Industrial Organization, Defined Industrial Organization: The study of the structure of firms and markets and of their interactions. Market Structure -
Markku Stenborg: Kilpailu- ja yhtiöoikeuden taloustiede0 Joensuu Mergers and Acquisitions Mergers are usually categorized by closeness of markets.
Market Power: Monopoly
Monopolistic Competition
Consumption, Production, Welfare B: Monopoly and Oligopoly (partial eq) Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester 2013.
1 Compare Monopoly to Competition. 2 Compare monopoly with competition The main results here are the ideas that ----1) a monopoly firm will charge a higher.
Chapter Twelve Pricing.
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
Chapter 2: Basic Microeconomic Tools 1 Basic Microeconomic Tools.
Monopolistic Competition
Chapter 9 – Profit maximization
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Twelve Pricing and Advertising.
Monopolistic Competiton. Assumptions Many sellers and many buyers Slightly different products Easy entry and exit (low barriers)
Antitrust Analysis Using Calibrated Economic Models Gregory J. Werden Senior Economic Counsel Antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice The views expressed.
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
Part 5 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Perfect Competition.
Profit Maximization and the Decision to Supply
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
Monopolistic Competition
 Firm that is sole seller of product without close substitutes  Price Maker not a Price Taker  There are barriers to entry thru: Monopoly Resources,
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
4 Market Structures Candy Markets Simulation.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Monopoly Gail (Gas Authority of India), which has had a monopoly in the gas transmission sector, is set to see some tough competition in the coming days.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
©2002 South-Western College Publishing
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
1 Quiz next Thursday (March 15) Problem Set given next Tuesday (March 13) –Due March 29 Writing Assignment given next Tuesday (March 13) –Due April 3.
Monopoly ETP Economics 101. Monopoly  A firm is considered a monopoly if...  it is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not have close.
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 7. Monopoly Prof. Vera Adamchik.
Sample Questions for Exam 3
Market structure and competition By A.V. Vedpuriswar.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
CHAPTER 21 PURE COMPETITION COMPETITION.
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Chapter 6 The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly.
Chapter 22 Microeconomics Unit III: The Theory of the Firm.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
A monopolistically competitive market is characterized by three attributes: many firms, differentiated products, and free entry. The equilibrium in a monopolistically.
Monopolistic competition Chapter Laugher Curve In Canada, there is a small radical group that refuses to speak English and no one can understand.
Monopoly and Oligopoly Announcements See web page for all exam information. Please get to exam rooms on time and have your CU ID ready to show the proctor.
Unit 10 MARKET POWER: Monopoly and Monopsony. Outcomes Define monopoly market power Identify sources of monopoly power Determine the social cost of monopoly.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power BEC Managerial Economics.
Chapter 12 Monopoly. Basic Definitions Imperfect Competition: Occurs when firms in a market or industry have some control over the price of their output.
Competitors and Competition
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 15 Monopoly.
ECN 3103 Industrial Organisation
Monopolistic competition and Oligopoly
Perfect Competition.
1 Market Structure And Competition Chapter Chapter Thirteen Overview 1.Introduction: Cola Wars 2.A Taxonomy of Market Structures 3.Monopolistic.
Micro Review Day 3 and 4. Perfect Competition 14 A Perfectly Competitive Market For a market to be perfectly competitive, six conditions must be met:
LESSON 7 PERFECT COMPETITION & MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION.
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 2
Pure Competition in the Short-Run
Horizontal Mergers: theory and practice
Chapter 2: Basic Microeconomic Tools
Profit maximization.
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Horizontal Mergers: theory and practice
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Presentation transcript:

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Mergers are usually categorized by closeness of markets that firms operate in Horizontal merger –Merging firms operate in same relevant market, firms are directly competing –Market shares in relevant markets change as result of merger Vertical merger –Merging firms operate at different stages of a production or distribution chain –Firms products belong to same relevant market do not compete horizontally –At least one firm can potentially be using the other firms' products as inputs in its production

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Conglomerate merger –Mergers not belonging to those above –Product extension Products of the firms not competing but firms use close marketing channels or production processes –Market extension Products are competing but relevant geographic markets are separate –Pure conglomerate mergers (none of those mentioned) Effects of Merger Suppose duopoly which behaves competitively Assume firms have identical cost functions and constant returns to scale prevail –MC 1 = AC 1, there are no fixed costs

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Profit maximization under perfect competition forces firms to price at marginal cost: p c = MC 1 Case 1: Merger to monopoly and costs stay at original level –Profit maximization rule (MC = MR) implies output Q m1 and price level p m1 so that deadweight loss DL 1 takes place –DL = (Q c - Q m1 )(p m1 - p c )/2 –This is strict decrease welfare –Also, merger means an income transfer from customers to owners of newco. –In this case, there would be reasons to block merger –Merger needs to be blocked for its deadweight loss creating effect, not because it means income redistribution

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Case 2: Merger involves synergies –Assume cost savings occur through decrease in marginal costs –MC 1 decreases to MC 2 –Monopoly profit maximization implies price level p m2 which is lower than that without cost savings p m1 –Deadweight loss occurs, but it is smaller than that without cost savings –DL = (Q c - Q m2 )(p m2 - p c )/2 –Cost savings due to the decrease in MC Amount is (p c -MC 2 )Q m2 –Efficiency is increased due to cost savings and decreased due to market power - deadweight loss

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Case 2 illustrates typical situation in antitrust –Many types of decisions and conduct by firms may be harmful for welfare while increasing it in other ways –From antitrust authority point of view, we face a trade- off –To determine whether certain conduct or decisions to merge are harmful on welfare, the authority should compare gains and losses to welfare In US, this seems to be the case, efficiency defence In EU, efficiency gains are more of reason to block merger, efficiency offense Difference partly due to legislation? –Market dominance in EU –Significant lessening of competition in US

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Incentives for horizontal mergers Salant, Switzer & Reynolds (QJE, 1982) Merger in Cournot market Assume an industry structure characterized by: –n identical firms (cost functions are identical) –Cournot or capacity competition –Constant returns to scale: C(q i ) = C(q) = cq, c > 0 –Linear demand is assumed linear: p(Q) = a - bQ, a,b > 0 –No possibilities for entry Profit function of any firm is then Firm i's Cournot-Nash equilibrium profit is

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Merger between any two firms: there is one firm less in the industry than before –n firm industry changes into n-1 firm industry Suppose m of n firms decide to merge (1 < m < n) m firms have incentive to merge if being part of merged entity gives more profit than staying unmerged, that is, if that is if Define LHS = A

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Case 1: m=1 Notice that only if n=2, merger is profitable Monopoly created Hence, only if in duopoly both firms merge we have the merger being in all firms' interest Case 2: m=2 Notice that only if n=3, merger is profitable –This again means we have a monopoly being created –Only if in triopoly all firms merge, merger is in all firms' interest

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Case 3: m=5 If n=6, merger is profitable: monopoly created But now even with n=7 merging is profitable –Creation of a duopoly through merger is profitable With n=8, merger is again unprofitable More generally Notice that which is < 0 Thus, A is decreasing in n, number of firms in industry More there are firms before merger, other things equal, more difficult it is for merger to be profitable for merging firms

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Notice also that which is > 0 Thus, A is increasing in m, number of firms that decide to merge –More there are firms that take part in merger, other things equal, easier it is for merger to be profitable for merging firms Irrespective of value of m or n, only if 80 % of firms in industry takes part in merger, merger is profitable Merger to monopoly is always in firms' interest Typical Cournot model where nothing but number of firms changes  price level increases after merger This follows from quantity competition since quantities are strategic substitutes

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Decrease in output by one firm is (partly) matched by an increase in output by rival firm In Cournot model, once some firms merge, they decrease their total output, as they act as single firm Firms not party to merger increase their output Under many parameter values, firms which mostly benefit from merger are non-merging firms –Business stealing effect Model says that mergers are not usually profitable Then we should not usually observe mergers, assuming that firms are rationally behaving agents! Not a good description of the real world where mergers are taking place in increasing numbers Model misses some essential aspects of the phenomenon –Mergers occur endogenously, not exogenously –Cost savings needs be incorporated

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions In Salant et al. one reason for mergers being unprofitable due to strategic substitutes –Decrease in production of some firms is matched by an increase in production by the competitors One way to overcome this effect is to assume U-shaped costs (strictly convex costs) –Rivals have less incentive for expansion of production as costs are increased –Mergers are more probable than in Salant et al Mergers in Bertrand Market In models above firms' strategies were quantities Deneckere & Davidson (RJE 1985) merger incentives under price competition Prices are strategic complements –Price increase by some firms is matched by price increase of rival firms –Reaction functions are upward sloping

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions In differentiated products Bertrand model firms engage in price competition Price increase followed by merger is matched by price increase of rivals –Reaction of outsiders reinforces initial price increase that results from merger –Then merger of any size is beneficial for merging firms –No business stealing effect Notice that this model predicts industries would usually evolve into monopoly! This, luckily, is not really what happens in real world There seems to be forces which prevent monopolization –These forces are not easily modelled and simple models do not descibe real world phenomena in satisfying way

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Notice that busines stealing effect is very much true in real world –Often, firms benefiting from mergers are non-merging firms –Thus, usually Cournot competition best describes real world phenomena, this holds with merger theory as well In preceding models acquiring and target firms were not differentiated Firms were ”black boxes”, mere MC-functions –Only effect is reduction in number of (symmetric) firms In real world acquisitions, there usually is buying and selling side in transaction Transaction creates a larger entity Seller sets price based on many factors –Asset value of the firm –Expected evolution of industry (expected profits)

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Kamien & Zang (QJE 1990): In quantity competition, does monopolization of industries take place when acquisition process is endogenous? In quantity game, total industry profit increases with a decreasing number of firms Any firm increases its profit as number of firms in industry diminishes –This follows from the nature of Cournot competition Seller knows that it would gain in profits if it would sell later rather than sooner As a consequence of this, sellers want to ask more than buyers want to pay –Monopoly profit is maximum buyer can pay In Cournot model following can be showed: complete monopolization of an industry is possible only if originally there were only a few firms in industry

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Welfare effects of mergers Merger without cost savings reduces welfare; if merger involves cost savings, we have trade-off Farrell & Shapiro (AER 1990) is most thorough model on welfare implications of horizontal mergers –Quantity competition and general demand structures –Cost-savings are allowed –Mergers without synergies increase price and hurt consumers –Cost saving is proportional to post-merger output –Deadweight loss is proportional to output reduction –If cost saving outweigh the deadweight loss, net welfare effect of merger is positive

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Merger simulation Market definition is hard with differentiated goods and can be misleading –Market definition is {0,1} decision, good is ”in” or ”out” –In reality goods belong to [0,1], they pose varying degree of competitive pressure to each other Increase in market power is interesting, not market definition Pure structural analysis of competitive effects can be misleading Simulation uses economic models grounded in theory to predict effect of mergers on prices in relevant markets Simulation allows direct measuring of changes in market power –Easier than measuring of market power

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Simulation allows to evaluate likelihood of synergies offsetting price increases Simulation requires estimation of demands –Minimum: own and cross-price elasticities Merger simulation: the big picture –Demand estimation Create demand models Get data and estimate demands Calibrate demand model(s) –constant elasticity –linear –logit –AIDS, etc to produce pre-merger prices, quantities, and demand elasticities

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Calibrate model: set parameters so that it exactly predicts pre-merger equilibrium –Plugging pre-merger prices into model must yield pre-merger shares Predict post-merger marginal costs –Try to evaluate synergies –Use demand model & post-merger costs to compute post-merger prices –Idea: if post-merger prices are well above pre-merger level, transaction increases market power Measuring market power is hard –Market power = L –L = (p-c)/p  [0, 1/e] so that eL  [0, 1] –has basically same info content as L –Quality of market power measure depends on accuracy of estimates of marginal costs and demand elasticity

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions –Data and estimation problems lead to biased measure of market power Why would measuring changes in market power be easier? –Estimated price change reacts less to estimated MC or demand, as we use same ”instrument” to measure pre and post-merger market power Limitation of simulation: price increase predictions are sensitive to functional form used for demand –Functional form of demand determines magnitude of price increases from merger –Linear and logit demand yield smallest price increases –Constant elasticity and AIDS demand typically yield price increases that are at least several times larger than those with linear or logit demand

HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Mergers and Acquisitions Use calibrated models in manner that makes them insensitive to functional form of demand –Compute compensating marginal cost reductions (CMCR) that exactly offsets price-increasing effects –CMCRs do not depend on functional form of demand as pre and post merger equilibrium prices and quantities are precisely same –If merger synergies appear likely to reduce merging firms’ cost as much as CMCRs, merger is unlikely to harm consumers –If merger synergies clearly fall well short, significant price increases are likely Visit –Fool around with Linear Bertrand Merger –If you have access to Mathematica, take a look at SimMerger to get feeling of what simulation is about