Social welfare economics foundations for CBA G. Mason 2010.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Effective Rate of Protection
Advertisements

Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes
Public Goods and Tax Policy
Consumer’s and Producer’s Surpluses
Valuation 2 and 3: Demand and welfare theory
Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by sellers.  An equilibrium.
Welfare measurement: individual CS, CV, EV and PS
Optimal Commodity Taxation
Consumer Theory.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Frank Cowell: Efficiency-Waste EFFICIENCY: WASTE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Welfare and Efficiency Almost essential.
Welfare Analysis. Ranking Economic systems  Objective: to find a criteria that allows us to rank different systems or allocations of resources.  This.
Unit 1: Trade Theory Standard Trade Model 2/6/2012.
A Definition of Economics
Chapter 21 - Consumer Choice
The Instruments of Trade Policy
Lectures 4-5: The specific factors model
Chapter 14 – Efficient and Equitable Taxation
Valuation 3: Welfare Measures Willingness to pay and willingness to act compensation Equivalent variation versus compensating variation Price changes versus.
AGEC 608 Lecture 02, p. 1 AGEC 608: Lecture 2 Objective: Review conceptual foundations of CBA Readings: –Boardman, Chapter 2 –Kankakee, Sections I and.
Chapter 8 The Instruments of Trade Policy
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
Chapter 20 – Consumer Choice
Willingness to Pay - is the maximum amount a person would be willing to pay, sacrifice or exchange for a good Consumer Surplus – the value to a consumer.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
The Instruments of Trade Policy
ECMB36 LECTURE NOTES MEASURING CHANGES IN SOCIAL WELFARE Townley, Chapter 5.
Introduction: Thinking Like an Economist 1 CHAPTER 2 CHAPTER 12 The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand The theory of economics.
Overview Aggregating preferences The Social Welfare function The Pareto Criterion The Compensation Principle.
Demand, Supply, & Market Equilibrium Chapter 3. Demand A schedule or curve that shows the various amounts of a product that consumers are willing and.
Welfare economics Outline Expressing changes in human well-being (utility) in monetary terms Deciding between monetary measures that are equally theoretically.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 9: Applications of Consumer Choice.
CHAPTER 8.  Import tariffs  Export subsidies  Import quotas  Voluntary export restraints (VER)  Local content requirements Copyright © 2009 Pearson.
Utility and Demand CHAPTER 7. 2 After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain what limits a household’s consumption choices Describe preferences.
PARETO OPTIMALITY AND THE EFFICIENCY GOAL
Consumer behaviorslide 1 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Preferences. The conflict between opportunities and desires. Utility maximizing behavior.
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
 Consumer welfare from a good is the benefit a consumer gets from consuming that good in excess of the cost of the good.  If you buy a good for exactly.
The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply
Chapter 5 Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis
Economics Unit Three Part I: Demand. Demand Essentially, demand is the willingness (or desire) to buy a good or service and the ability to pay for it.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Monopoly 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied,
Chapter 3: Individual Markets: Demand & Supply
Demand Defined Demand Graphed Changes in Demand Supply Defined Supply Graphed Changes in Supply Equilibrium Surpluses Shortages Individual Markets: Demand.
Econ 201 Ch. 6 & 8 Government Policy & Economic Welfare.
Consumer’s and Producer’s Surplus Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 3
Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Lecture 3 [Chapter 3]
Markets Markets – exchanges between buyers and sellers. Supply – questions faced by sellers in those exchanges are related to how much to sell and at.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Demand: The Benefit Side of the Market. 2 Law of Demand  Law of Demand  People do less of what they want to do as the cost of doing it rises  Recall.
Consumer choices The Benefit Side of Demand Chapter 5.
The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand 10 The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand The theory of.
Econ 201 Ch. 8 Government Policy & Economic Welfare.
Chapter 9 International Trade. Objectives 1. Understand the basis of international specialization 2. Learn who gains and who loses from international.
Consumer Decision Making Frederick University 2014.
Utility- is the satisfaction you receive from consuming a good or service Total utility is the number of units of utility that a consumer gains from consuming.
Economics Efficiency/inefficiency 1.  Recall, one role for the government:  Improve efficiency  When markets cannot cope  Other ones: rules, distribution.
International Economics: Theory and Policy, Sixth Edition
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternCallan and Thomas, Environmental Economics and Management,
Farid Abolhassani A Simple Model of Demand 3. Learning Objectives After working through this chapter, you will be able to: Define the term ‘quantity demanded’
We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets?
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2008 Chapter 5 Consumer choice and demand decisions David Begg, Stanley Fischer and Rudiger Dornbusch, Economics, 9th Edition,
Government Policy & Economic Welfare
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc. to accompany Exploring Economics 3rd Edition by Robert L. Sexton Copyright © 2005 Thomson Learning, Inc. Thomson.
Government Policy & Economic Welfare
WELFARE FOUNDATION OF CBA
Government Policy & Economic Welfare Week 4
Presentation transcript:

Social welfare economics foundations for CBA G. Mason 2010

Under consumption of public good What examples exist of public goods you care that others under consume? What examples of public goods make no difference that others under- consume?

Direct and inverse demand Direct demand views quantity as the “dependent” variable and price as the “independent” variable or the driver. –Q A = A 0 - A 1 P A Inverse demand, views price as a marginal utility and measure of the willingness to pay for a specific quantity. –P A = A 0 + A 1 Q A

Social welfare rules Few actions by government make everyone better off; usually there are several winners and several losers. Who are the winners and losers in the following scenarios –Street repairs –Subsidies to the arts and culture –Mandatory vaccination of girls (under 12) for HPV (see facts sheets)

Pareto Rules 1 Program X improves the welfare of society if it makes at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off. Adler and Posner (reading cited in outline) identify several factors that prevent this rule for working. –Un observability of states of welfare –Un comparability of welfare among individuals Declining marginal utility of money suggests that those who are well off, would be worsened, if many others who are poor are made better off.

Pareto 2 Assume a social preference function (aggregate demand for a public good) given by: U(X 1,X 2, …X N ). Also assume H households in a community, and a single road. Cyclists would like a bike path; council must decide. If the bike path is built, the average household will experience utility increase of ΔU. Council has an easy decision if: –ΔU h > 0 for all households and ΔU h > 0 for at least one household, or if –ΔU h < 0 for at all one household and (ΔU h <0 for one household)

Pareto 3 Most situations involve a mix of households that experience increases, neutral or negative utilities from a bike path (Who loses from a bike path?) Naïve solution is add utilities –U tot = ΔU 1 + ΔU 2 +…. ΔU h Utility is an ordinal measure, not cardinal That means we cannot compare utilities directly

Willingness to Pay Compensating Variation Beneficiaries of bike path –What is the maximum amount you are willing to pay to have the bike path constructed? Opponents of bike path –What is the minimum amount you are willing to accept of the bike path were constructed. This is a proxy for the change in utility from the perspective of adopting the new. For household h, if compensating variation is CV h >0, then ΔU h > 0; if CV h <0, then ΔU h < 0; and if CV h =0, then ΔU h = 0.

Willingness to Pay Equivalent Variation Beneficiaries of bike path –What is the minimum amount you would accept to forgo the bike path? Opponents of the bike path –What is the maximum amount you would be willing to pay to stop the bike path? This is the proxy for utility from the perspective of preserving the old. For household h, if equivalent variation is EV h >0, then ΔU h > 0; if EV h <0, then ΔU h < 0; and if EV h =0, then ΔU h = 0.

BeneficiariesOpponents Compensating Variation Move to New Payment to get project Payment to accept project Equivalent Variation Maintain the Old Payment received to forgo project Payment to prevent bike path Several methods exist to measure willingness to pay, including revealed preference (demand studies) and direct surveys. These will be reviewed in more detail, later in the course

First compensation rule It may be tempting to conduct a survey and then add CV h across all households. If CVh > 0 this is the first compensation test in public policy Issues –To ensure Pareto optimality, those whose welfare declines with the change must actually be compensated. (This raises mechanical issues of getting winners to pay losers). It also causes strategic biases if survey respondents raise “price” to get more money (ie., overstate their need for compensation) –Marginal utility of income means that one can compare CV and EV only for those at the same income. Key assumption of CBA – Government uses tax and transfer policies to ensure an optimal distribution of income, such that the marginal utility of income is equivalent for all.

Second compensation rule If EVh > 0 this is the second compensation test in public policy (subject to equal marginal utilities of income). This is the preservation scenario. If EV>0, then the minimum amount needed by cyclists to forgo the path, exceeds the maximum amount opponents would be willing to pay to preserve the status quo. This means the project proceeds If EV<0, then the opponents can buy off the beneficiaries and the project does not proceed.

Combining the rules 1.CV> 0, EV > 0 (proceed) –Both compensation rules are satisfied. Winners can compensate losers if the project were build, and losers could not compensate winners if the project were not built. If path does not exist, build it; the path exists retain it. 2.EV<0, CV<0 (do nor proceed) –Those who gain fro the status quo can compensate those who want the project; if the project exists, those that want to cancel it, can compensate those that want to maintain it. If the path does not exist, do not build it; if it exists, destroy it. 3.CV>0, EV<0 –If there no path, winners can compensate losers. If there is a path, losers can compensate winners. If there is no path, build it; if a path exists, get rid of it! 4.EV>0, CV<0 –EV>0 implies that if there is a path, then destroying it would cause a welfare loss; if CV<0, then if there is no path, constructing it would cause a welfare loss. The third and fourth situations are the essence of what is called the Scitovsky paradox or Scitovsky reversal If EV and CV are negative reject the project; If EV and CV are positive, adopt the project. Combinations 3 and 4 offer no guidance, and the status quo should be maintained, pending more data.

Consumer surplus At P 1, consumers are willing to buy X 1. At smaller quantities, they are prepared to pay more, but not have to. “a” is the consumer surplus at P 1 When prices drop, consumer surplus rises to a+b+c

Consumer surplus and CV,EV Normal goods – EV>ΔCS>CV Inferior goods – EV<ΔCS<CV EV= ΔCS=CV when income elasticity is zero. In general, measures of consumer surplus perform reasonably well in measuring changes in social welfare

Changes due to price of substitutes and complements Assume that X, Y and Z are three commodities Y is substitute for X and Z is a complement of X. A price decrease in X, reduces demand for Y, and increases the demand for Z

Price of X increases, reduces the demand for Y Price of X increases, increase the demand for z Overall income has not changed: Therefore b+d+f+g+h = d+e+f+h+j Rearranging b = e – g + j And therefore b+c = (c + e) – g +j Refer to previous figure as well for b, c d, and e Recall that b+c was the increase in consumer surplus from a price reduction in x

Change in undistorted markets Undistorted means that P = MC Price of X drops, but demand for the substitute Y falls and increases for the complement ΔB=c+e-g+j ΔW = ΔB - ΔC

ΔW = [c+e-g+j] – [e-g+j], or market by market ΔW = [c+e-e] +[-g+g] + [j-j], x y z

Distorted markets The economy has three goods – J, K, L. L is a composite good representing all other goods except J and K The price of J rises from P1 to P2. The demand drops for J, but rises for K and L. The price of K is distorted because it is less than its marginal cost. J, K, and L are assumed to be substitutes – when the price of J drops the demand for K and l increases.

In market J, consumers lose k + m In markets K and L, they receive n + r. ΔB = n + r – (k + m) The resource cost declines for J = m, increases for K (q + n) and L (r) ΔW = ΔB - ΔW = q + n + r - m