Lecture 2 An Introduction to Contracts This lecture completes our discussion of bargaining by showing what happens when there is incomplete information.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Advertisements

Contracts and Moral Hazards
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection. What does it mean Adverse Selection (AS)? There is an AS problem when: before the signing of the contract,
A Disneyland dilemma: Two-part tariffs for a mickey mouse monopoly
Seminar in Auctions and Mechanism Design Based on J. Hartline’s book: Approximation in Economic Design Presented by: Miki Dimenshtein & Noga Levy.
 Introduction  Simple Framework: The Margin Rule  Model with Product Differentiation, Variable Proportions and Bypass  Model with multiple inputs.
Auctions. Strategic Situation You are bidding for an object in an auction. The object has a value to you of $20. How much should you bid? Depends on auction.
Pablo Serra Universidad de Chile Forward Contracts, Auctions and Efficiency in Electricity Markets.
Chapter 8 A roadmap ahead: So far we have studied how aggregate economic performance is defined and measured. In the next few chapters we will study the.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Chapter 14 Infinite Horizon 1.Markov Games 2.Markov Solutions 3.Infinite Horizon Repeated Games 4.Trigger Strategy Solutions 5.Investing in Strategic Capital.
Chapter Thirty-Three Law and Economics. Effects of Laws u Property right assignments affect –asset, income and wealth distributions; v e.g. nationalized.
1 Unless otherwise noted, the content of this course material is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution – Non-Commercial 3.0 License.
Game Theory The study of rational behavior among interdependent agents Agents have a common interest to make the pie as large as possible, but Agents have.
Chapter 16 Negotiation 1.Costly Agreements 2.Ultimatum game with Incomplete Information 3.Counteroffers with Incomplete Information 4.The revelation principle.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 1 The Fundamentals of Managerial Economics.
Lecture 4 on Individual Optimization Risk Aversion
Productivity, Output, and Employment
More on Vertical Relationships. The Make or Buy Decision Firms should internalize those activities that can be conducted within the firm more profitably.
Goods Prices and Factor Prices: The Distributional Consequences of International Trade Nothing is accomplished until someone sells something. (popular.
Incomplete Contracts Renegotiation, Communications and Theory December 10, 2007.
Asymmetric Information
1 External Costs. 2 Overview An externality is a situation where a third party is affected by an economic activity. The externality can be either positive.
Two-Stage Games APEC 8205: Applied Game Theory Fall 2007.
Part 7 Further Topics © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Managerial Economics Managerial Economics = economic theory + mathematical eco + statistical analysis.
Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,
Chapter 17 Full Information 1.An Introductory Example 2.Service Contracts 3.Employment Contracts 4.The Role of Uncertainty 5.Insider Financing.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Our final lecture analyzes optimal contracting in situations when the principal writing the contract has less information than the agent who accepts or.
Chapter 15: Job Search: External and Internal
Chapter 23 Competitive Equilibrium
Lecture 2 in Contracts Employment Contracts This lecture studies how those who create and administer organizations design the incentives and institutional.
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
The Moral Hazard Problem Stefan P. Schleicher University of Graz
Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes
Economics 2010 Lecture 12 Perfect Competition. Competition  Perfect Competition  Firms Choices in Perfect Competition  The Firm’s Short-Run Decision.
The Supply Curve and the Behavior of Firms
Auction and Markets Professor Robert A. Miller January 2010 Teaching assistant:Hao Xue
Lecture 5 Financial Incentives This lecture is paired with our previous one that discussed employee benefits. Here we focus on the reasons why monetary.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
This lecture introduces a second principle for solving games with only singleton information sets, perfect information games. Examples of these games are.
Lecture 7 Course Summary The tools of strategy provide guiding principles that that should help determine the extent and nature of your professional interactions.
Lecture 8 Profit Maximization. Comparison of consumer theory with producer theory In consumer theory we learned that the main objective of consumer is.
1 Resource Markets CHAPTER 11 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Lecture 5A Mixed Strategies and Multiplicity Not every game has a pure strategy Nash equilibrium, and some games have more than one. This lecture shows.
Lecture 5 Financial Incentives This lecture is paired with our previous one that discussed employee benefits. Here we focus on the reasons why monetary.
© 2010 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Chapter 7 Incentive Mechanism Principle-Agent Problem Production with Teams Competition.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 17 Choice Making Under Uncertainty.
Lecture 1 in Contracts Nonlinear Pricing This lecture studies how those who create and administer organizations design the incentives and institutional.
This lecture analyzes how well competitive equilibrium predicts industry outcomes as a function the of the production technology, the number of firms and.
Lecture 1 on Bargaining Setting the Agenda This lecture focuses on the well known problem of how to split the gains from trade or, more generally, mutual.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
A Supplier’s Optimal Quantity Discount Policy Under Asymmetric Information Charles J. Corbett Xavier de Groote Presented by Jing Zhou.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
The Base Model. Objectives of the chapter Describe the basic elements of the Basic Principal-Agent model Study the contracts that will emerge when information.
By: Donté Howell Game Theory in Sports. What is Game Theory? It is a tool used to analyze strategic behavior and trying to maximize his/her payoff of.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
Lecture 5 on Auctions Monopoly We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling multiple.
Lecture 4 on Auctions Multiunit Auctions We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling.
1 Chapter 11 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION. 2 Profit Maximization A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the sole goal of achieving.
Lecture 5 Bargaining This lecture focuses on the well known problem of how to split the gains from trade or, more generally, mutual interaction when the.
Perfect Competition: Short Run and Long Run
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
The Role of Government Chapter 14
Chapter Thirty-Three Law and Economics.
Lecture 10 Coordination and Reputation
Lecture 4 Bargaining and Contracts
Presentation transcript:

Lecture 2 An Introduction to Contracts This lecture completes our discussion of bargaining by showing what happens when there is incomplete information when one party has more information than another. Then we study how those who create and administer organizations design the incentives and institutional rules that best serve their ends. To demonstrate how to extract the most rent from a transaction, we analyze upstream contracts with suppliers, employment contracts for workers, and service contracts for consumers.

Bargaining with full information Two striking features characterize all the solutions of the bargaining games that we have played so far: 1. An agreement is always reached. 2. Negotiations end after one round. This occurs because nothing is learned from continuing negotiations, yet a cost is sustained because the opportunity to reach an agreement is put at risk from delaying it.

Reaching agreement may be costly Yet there are many situations where conflict is not instantaneously resolved, and where negotiations break down: 1. In industrial relations, negotiations can be drawn out, and sometimes lead to strikes. 2. Plans for construction projects are discussed, contracts are written up, but left unsigned, so the projects are cancelled. 3. Weddings are postponed and called off.

The blame game Consider the following experiment in a multi-round bargaining game called BLAME. There are two players, called BBC and a GOVT. At the beginning of the game BBC makes a statement, which is a number between zero and one, denoted N. (Interpret N as a proportion of blame BBC is prepared to accept.) The GOVT can agree with the BBC statement N or refute it. If the GOVT agrees with the statement then the BBC forfeits £N billion funding, and the GOVT loses 1 - N proportion of the vote next election.

Counter proposal If the GOVT refutes the statement, there is a 20 percent chance that no one at all will be blamed, because a more newsworthy issue drowns out the conflict between BBC and GOVT. If the GOVT refutes the statement, and the issue remains newsworthy (this happens with probability 0.8), the GOVT issues its own statement P, also a number between zero and one. (Interpret P as a proportion of blame the GOVT offers to accept.) Should the BBC agree with the statement issued by the GOVT, the GOVT loses P proportion of the vote in the next election, and the BBC loses £5(1-P) billion in funds.

Endgame Otherwise the BBC refutes the statement of the GOVT, an arbitrator called HUTTON draws a random variable from a uniform distribution with support [0,2] denoted H, the BBC is fined £H billion, and the GOVT loses H/5 proportion of the vote next election. What will happen? The solution can be found using backwards induction. (See the footnotes or read the press!)

Evolving payoffs and discount factors Suppose two (or more) parties are jointly liable for a debt that neither wishes to pay. The players take turns in announcing how much blame should be attributed to each player, and the game ends if a sufficient number of them agree with a tabled proposal. If a proposal is rejected, the total liability might increase (since the problem remains unsolved), or decline (if there is some chance the consequences are less dire than the players originally thought). If the players do not reach a verdict after a given number of rounds, another mechanism, such as an independent enquiry, ascribes liability to each player.

Summarizing bargaining outcomes when there is complete information If the value of the match is constant throughout the bargaining phase, and is known by both parties, then the preceding discussion shows that it will be formed immediately, or not at all. The only exception occurs if the current value of the match changes throughout the bargaining phase as the players gather new information together.

Bargaining with incomplete information If the value of the match is constant throughout the bargaining phase, and is known by both parties, then the preceding discussion shows that it will be formed immediately, or not at all. In the segment on this topic, we will relax the assumption that all the bargaining parties are fully informed. We now modify the original ultimatum game, between a proposer and a responder, by changing the information structure. Suppose the value to the responder of reaching an agreement is not known by the proposer.

An experiment In this game: 1. The proposer demands s from the responder. 2. Then the responder draws a value v from the probability distribution F(v). For convenience we normalize v so that v 0  v  v The responder either accepts or rejects the demand of s. 4. If the demand is accepted the proposer receives s and the responder receives v – s, but if the demand is rejected neither party receives anything.

The proposer’s objective The responder accepts the offer if v > s and rejects the offer otherwise. Now suppose the proposer maximizes his expected wealth, which can be expressed as: Pr{v > s}s = [1 – F(s)]s Notice the term in the square brackets [1 – F(s)] is the quantity sold, which declines in price, while s is the price itself.

Solution to the game Let s o denote the optimal choice of s for the proposer. Clearly v 0  s o < v 1. If v 0 < s o < v 1, then s o satisfies a first order condition for this problem: 1 – F’(s o ) s o – F(s o ) = 0 Otherwise s o = v 0 and the proposer receives: [1 – F(v 0 )]v 0 = v 0 The revenue generated by solving the first order condition is compared with v 0 to obtain the solution to the proposer’s problem.

F(s) is a uniform distribution Suppose: F(v) = (v – v 0 )/ (v 1 – v 0 ) for all v 0  v  v 1 which implies F’(v) = 1 /(v 1 – v 0 ) for all v 0  v  v 1 Thus the first order condition reduces to: 1 – s o /(v 1 – v 0 ) – (s o – v 0 )/ (v 1 – v 0 ) = 0 => v 1 – v 0 – s o – s o + v 0 = 0 => 2 s o = v 1

Solving the uniform distribution case In the interior case s o = v 1 /2. It clearly applies when v 0 = 0, but that is not the only case. We compare v 0 with the expected revenue from the interior solution v 1 (v 1 – 2v 0 )/(v 1 – v 0 ). If v 0 > 0 define v 1 = kv 0 for some k > 1. Then we obtain an interior solution if k > 1 and: k(k – 2) > k – 1 => k 2 – 3k + 1 > 0 So an interior solution holds if and only if k exceeds the larger of the two roots to this equation, that is k > ( /2 )/2.

F(s) is [0,1] uniform More specifically let: F(v) = v for all 0  v  1 Then the interior solution applies so s o = ½, and F(v) = ½. Thus exchange only occurs half the time it there are gains from trade. The trading surplus is: Given our assumption about F(v) it follows that ¼ of the trading surplus is realized, which is ½ of the potential surplus.

Counteroffers Since there is only one offer, there is no opportunity for learning to take place during the bargaining process. We now extend the bargaining phase by allowing the player with private information to make an initial offer. If rejected, the bargaining continues for one final round. For convenience we assume throughout this discussion that F(v) is uniform [0,1].

Solution when there are counteroffers The textbook analyzes solutions of the following type: 1. There is a threshold valuation v* such that in the first found every manager with valuation v > v* offers the same wage w*, and every manager with valuation v < v* offers lower wages. 2. In the first round the union rejects every offer below w*, and accepts all other offers. 3. If the bargaining continues to the final round the union solves the first order condition for the one round problem using the valuations of the manager as truncated at v*.

Outcomes of two round bargaining game Note that if the probability of continuation is too high, management will not offer anything in the first round, because it would reveal too much about its own private value v. In this case the bargaining process stalls because management find it strategically beneficial to withhold information that can be used against them.

Designing the bargaining rules An implication of our studies on bargaining is the manifest value from setting the rules and conventions that determine how bargaining proceeds. Almost by definition managers are placed in a strong position to set the rules of bargaining games they play. In the remaining parts of this lecture we focus focus on upstream supply contracts, downstream consumer agreements, and employment contracts with labor.

A rent extraction problem Employers seek to minimize their wage bill, or in the case of sole proprietors loss in expected utility, subject to two constraints: 1. They must attract workers they wish to hire. This is called the participation constraint. 2. The workers must perform the tasks to which they are assigned. This constraint is called incentive compatibility.

Full information principal agent problem A firm wishes to build a new factory, and will hire a builder. How should it structure the contract? Firm:R L -w L Builder: w L -u L R H -w H w H -u H

Constraints facing the firm use backwards induction to solve the problem: We can use backwards induction to solve the problem: 1. The incentive compatibility constraint is: w H – u H  w L – u L if H w L – u L  w H – u H if L 2. The participation constraint is: w H - u H  0 if H w L - u L  0 if L

wHwH wLwL w H =u H w H -w L =u H -u L u H -u L u L -u H (IC) uHuH The constraints illustrated

Minimum cost of achieving L The minimum cost of achieving L is found by minimizing w L such that: 1. w L  u L 2. w L – u L  w H – u H The first constraint bounds w L from below by u L. Since u L  u H the second constraint is satisfied by not making the wage depend on effort. Therefore the minimum cost of achieving L is found by setting w* = u* L

Minimum cost of achieving H The minimum cost of achieving H is found by minimizing w L such that: 1. w H  u H 2. w H – u H  w L – u L The first constraint bounds w H from below by u H. Since u L  u H we must penalize the worker to deter him from choosing L, by setting: w L < w H – u H + u L w L < w H – u H + u L Therefore the minimum cost of achieving H is: w* H = u* H w* L = w H – u H + u L - Penalty

Profit maximization The net profits from achieving L are R L – u L * The net profits from achieving H are R H – u H * Therefore the firm hires a worker to achieve H if R H – u H * > R L – u L * and hires a worker to achieve only L otherwise.

Service provider Multipart pricing schemes are commonly found in the telecommunications industry, amusement parks. sport clubs, and time sharing vacation houses and small jets. In this example a provider incurs a fixed cost of c 0 to connect the consumer to the facility, and a marginal cost of c 1 for every unit provided. It follows that if the consumer purchases x units the total cost to the provider is: c 0 + c 1 x. We assume the monetary benefit to the consumer from a service level of x is: x 1/2. How should the provider contract with the consumer?

Optimal contracting To derive the optimal contract, we proceed in two steps: 1. derive the optimal level of service, by asking how much the consumer would use if she controlled the facility herself. 2. calculate the equivalent monetary benefit of providing the optimal level of service to the consumer, and sell it to the consumer if this covers the total cost to the provider. The equivalent monetary benefit can be extracted two ways, as membership fee with rights to consume up to a maximal level, or in a two part pricing scheme, where the consumer pays for use at marginal cost, plus a joining fee.

A parameterization In our example we maximize x 1/2 - c 0 - c 1 x with respect to x to obtain interior solution x = (2c 1 ) -2 It follows that the costs from an interior solution are: c 0 + 1/4c 1 and the monetary equivalent from consuming the optimal level of service is 1/2c 1. Therefore the provider extracts 1/2c 1 if: 4c 0 c 1 <1

Charging a uniform price If the service provider charges per unit instead, the consumer would respond by purchasing a level of service a a function of price. Anticipating the consumer’s demand, the provider constructs the consumer’s demand curve, and sets price where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. The provider serves the consumer if and only if the revenue from providing the service at this price exceeds the total cost. Since lower levels of service are provided, and since the consumer achieves a greater level of utility, than in the two part contract, the provider charging a unit price realizes less rent than in the two part contract.

The parameterization revisited In our example the consumer demands x = (2p) -2 where p is the uniform unit price of the service. The service provider maximizes: x 1/2 /2 - c 0 - c 1 x with respect to x to obtain the interior solution x = (4c 1 ) -2 which is the optimal choice if: 16c 0 c 1 <1

Comparing multipart with uniform pricing schemes Since lower levels of service are provided, and since the consumer achieves a greater level of utility, than in the two part contract, the provider charging a unit price realizes less rent than in the two part contract.