ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF FINANCE BASIC ELEMENTS OF THE THEORY OF CAPITAL.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
Advertisements

The Loanable Funds Market. Equilibrium Interest Rate Savers and buyers are matched in markets governed by supply and demand There are many markets, but.
Budget Today or Tomorrow
1 Interest Rate Determination Here we start with an example and end with a theory of changes in the interest rate.
The securities market economy -- theory Abstracting again to the two- period analysis - - but to different states of payoff.
Utility maximization The goal of the consumer is to maximize utility given the budget constraint. Let’s see what that means.
Investment and Saving Decisions
Indifference Curves and
Chapter 9 CONSUMER THEORY
Consumer Theory.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
Lecture 10: Consumption, Saving and Investment I L11200 Introduction to Macroeconomics 2009/10 Reading: Barro Ch.7 16 February 2010.
The Theory of Aggregate Demand Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the role of money in the classical model. Learn the relationship between.
Chapter 5 Consumer Choice and Demand Decisions
L4: Consumption and Saving1 Lecture 4: Consumption and Saving The following topics will be covered: –Consumption and Saving under Certainty Aversion to.
Now or later ECO61 Microeconomic Analysis Udayan Roy Fall 2008.
16:Investment, Capital, and Interest  Overview  How are business investment decisions made?  How are household saving decisions made?  How do investment,
8 CAPITAL, INVESTMENT, AND SAVING CHAPTER.
Chapter 23 CAPITAL Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Chapter 4. 2 The Theory of Production Representative Agent Economy: all output is produced from labor and capital and in.
Chapter 5 Consumer choice and demand decisions
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the determinants of output. Understand how output is distributed. Learn.
Assumptions for discussion on this topic In our class on National Income we saw that output Y = C + I + G + NX We shall ignore NX. This means we are assuming.
1 Ch. 7. At Full Employment: The Classical Model The relationship between the quantity of labor employed and real GDP What determines the full-employment.
The Market for Loanable Funds  For the economy as a whole, savings always equals investment spending  In a closed economy, savings is equal to national.
Endogenous growth Sophia Kazinnik University of Houston Economics Department.
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
Consumer Behavior 06 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
CHAPTER 4 INTEREST RATES. Copyright© 2003 John Wiley and Sons, Inc. What are Interest Rates? Cost of borrowing or the return on lending Price of money.
Capter 16 Output and Aggregate Demand 1 Chapter 16: Begg, Vernasca, Fischer, Dornbusch (2012).McGraw Hill.
Microeconomics Corso E John Hey. Chapter 26 The LABOUR MARKET The supply of labour. The demand for labour. Equilibrium. Minimum wage legislation?
The Loanable Funds Market. Equilibrium Interest Rate Savers and buyers are matched in markets governed by supply and demand There are many markets, but.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 5/1 Chapter 5 Intertemporal Decision Making and Capital Values.
Chapter 6 Markets, Prices, Supply, and Demand. Objective: understand short-run economic fluctuations. Micro foundations: the choices made by consumers.
1 Quick Review Utility Maximization Econ Fall 2007.
Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics Lecture 10 Investment, Savings and the Real Interest Rate The role of the Government Savings and Investment.
Demand Analysis Some Questions What is behind a consumer’s demand curve? How do consumers choose from among various consumer “goods”? What determines.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment.
Chapter 17 CAPITAL MARKETS.
The Modern Approach to Aggregate Demand The Demand for Money and the LM Curve.
©McGraw-Hill Education, 2014
© 2005 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Ltd. 1 Microeconomics, Chapter 6 The Theory of Consumer Choice SLIDES PREPARED BY JUDITH SKUCE, GEORGIAN COLLEGE.
6 | Consumer Choices • Consumption Choices
Inter-temporal Consumption Choice
Time preferences, value and interest Time preference Time value of money Simple and compound interest Determination of Market interest rate Market equilibrium.
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
Household Behavior and
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2008 Chapter 5 Consumer choice and demand decisions David Begg, Stanley Fischer and Rudiger Dornbusch, Economics, 9th Edition,
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
The Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account Professor Roberto Chang Rutgers University March 2013.
QUIZ FOUR The Consumer Theory. 1.According to the principle of diminishing marginal utility: A. The more of a good a consumer consumes the lower her total.
Micro Unit IV Chapters 25, 26, and The economic concepts are similar to those for product markets. 2. The demand for a factor of production is.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Lecture 26: The Labour Market The supply of labour (consumer: leisure time/money trade-off). The demand for labour (theory.
Inter-temporal Consumption Choice
THE LEVEL OF INTEREST RATES
Inter-temporal Consumption Choice
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice
06A Appendix Consumer Behavior
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Presentation transcript:

ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF FINANCE BASIC ELEMENTS OF THE THEORY OF CAPITAL

CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND RATE OF RETURN Let Co = current consumption and C1 = future consumption Then, let’s view consumption over time time consumption  Co  C1 t 1 t 2 t 3 Co At time period t 1 a consumer withholds current consumption Co, in the amount  Co and puts this amount to use to produce future consumption ---- So there is a rate of return that is derived on the withholding of Co Here, all withheld Co is used to produce consumption in time period t 2, and this is given as  C1 At time period t 1 a consumer withholds current consumption Co, in the amount  Co and puts this amount to use to produce future consumption ---- So there is a rate of return that is derived on the withholding of Co Here, all withheld Co is used to produce consumption in time period t 2, and this is given as  C1 The rate of return is given by (  C1/  Co) – 1 = r

CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND RATE OF RETURN In the previous case, the graph showed that the consumer withheld Co in t 1 to only consume in the next period t 2 Let’s look at a long term view time consumption  Co  C1 t 1 t 2 t 3 Co At time period t 1 the consumer withholds current consumption Co, in the amount  Co and puts this amount to use to produce perpetual future consumption So  Co is here used to get a perpetual  C1 The rate of return now is r ∞ = (  C1/  Co) – 1 At time period t 1 the consumer withholds current consumption Co, in the amount  Co and puts this amount to use to produce perpetual future consumption So  Co is here used to get a perpetual  C1 The rate of return now is r ∞ = (  C1/  Co) – 1

THE SINGLE PERIOD RATE OF RETURN The single period rate of return is given by, r 1 = (  C1 -  Co) /  Co= (  C1/  Co)- 1 If  C1 >  Co, then r 1 > 0 An example: If the consumer withholds 100 and this is put to use to yield 110 in the next period, then r 1 = 110/100 – 1, which is equal to 0.10 or 10% Or (1 + r 1 ) = 110/100

THE PERPETUAL RATE OF RETURN The consumer withholds current period consumption as  Co and gets a yield of  C1 perpetually So r ∞ = (  C1/  Co) - 1 What has happened is that the consumer gets Co + y, where y is some perpetual amount each period --- so r ∞ = y/  Co

The actual rate of return on capital accumulation given some sacrifice in present consumption is somewhere between the single period rate and the perpetual rate

The equilibrium rate of return We now introduce demand and supply in the market for the future goods to obtain an equilibrium rate of return We assume a 2-period analysis – now and then, or current and future The 1-period rate is r = (  C1/  Co) – 1 Or,  C1/  Co = 1 + r

So we now have how much Co has to be foregone to get an increase of 1 unit of future consumption, C1 This is the relative price of 1 unit of C1 in terms of Co This is the price of future goods

P 1 = the price of future goods = the quantity of present goods that must be foregone to increase future consumption by 1 unit P 1 =  Co/  C1 = 1/(1 + r) or P 1 =  Co = 1/(1 + r)  C1

Now we need to consider the demand for future goods Let the utility of current consumption, Co, vs. future consumption, C1, be given by some utility function, U( Co,C1) The consumer’s problem is to allocate wealth, given here as W, to the two goods, Co, and C1 Wealth, W, not spent on Co can be invested at a rate, r, to obtain C1 next period

Therefore, P 1 reflects the present cost of future consumption There is a budget constraint that imposes constraint on the consumer maximizing utility over Co and C1 W = Co + P 1 C1 is the budget constraint, indicating that wealth = current consumption, Co, plus the value of future consumption, P 1 C1

What does the consumer’s intertemporal problem look like? U1U1 U2U2 U3U3 Future Consumption C1 Current Consumption Co W/P 1 W C1* Co* W = Co + P 1 C1 Intertemporal utility or Indifference curves At the tangency of U 1 and the budget constraint, W, we get equilibrium consumption of Co, as Co*, and equilibrium future consumption, C1* The consumer maximizes intertemporal utility over current and future consumption given the budget constraint, which is the limit on wealth

From the budget constraint, W = Co + P 1 C1, and given the equilibrium Co and C1 as Co* and C1*, we get P 1 C1* = W – Co*, or C1* = (W – Co*)/P 1, which is equal to (W – Co*)(1 + r), since P 1 = 1/(1+r)

Intertemporal Utility The utility here (intertemporal utility) depends on how people feel about future consumption relative to present consumption (their impatience) This impatience is reflective of a consumer’s intertemporal time preference rate, say, 

Generally future utility is discounted by a rate of time preference, say of 1/(1+  ), for  > 0 If we assume that utility is also separable, we get U( Co,C1) = U(Co) + 1/(1 +  )U(C1)

Maximize Utility Therefore, we maximize Utility in mathematical form by using the classical optimization mathematics or the Lagrangian method of constrained maximization that we learned in Calculus

Max U(Co) + 1/(1+  )U(C1), subject to the wealth constraint, W = Co + C1/(1+ r), because P 1 = 1/(1 + r) The Lagrangian with the objective function, Max U(Co) + 1/(1+  )U(C1), and constraint, W = Co + C1/(1+ r) is: L = U(Co) + 1/(1+  )U(C1) + λ[W – Co – C1/(1+r)

Then, we find the first order conditions for a maximum, by taking the derivatives of the L with respect to Co, C1 and λ (with λ being the Lagrangian multiplier reflecting the effect of the constraint in the constrained optimization problem) We set these derivative equal to zero, that is we find the zero slope conditions which indicate an optimization

∂L/∂Co = U΄(Co) – λ = 0 ∂L/∂C1 = 1/(1+  )U΄(C1) – λ/(1+r) = 0 ∂L/∂ λ = W = Co – C1/(1+r) = 0 Where U΄(Co) = ∂U/∂Co, and U΄(C1)=∂U/∂C1 We can divide the first two derivatives, and rearrange to get U΄(Co) = ((1+r)/(1+  )) U΄(C1)

Therefore, Co = C1 if r = , or this says that Co = C1 if interest rate = time preference rate Co > C1 if  > r, or if the time preference rate is greater than the interest rate, that is to get U΄(Co) C1

So, whether C1 >, 0 But one may consume more in the future if the interest rate, r, on savings or investment is high enough

If  is the same for two persons, say A and B, but person A gets higher return, r, than does B, U΄(Co)/ U΄(C1) for A is greater than U΄(Co)/ U΄(C1) for B Hence, Co/C1 will be lower for A than for B

What happens if r changes? As r increases, this induces a lower price of C1, since P 1 = 1/(1+r), and consumption of C1 increases So we would get a downward sloping demand for future goods, C1 (but this is not unambiguously the case since there are other complications that are discussed in advanced microeconomics)

The equilibrium in the market Supply Demand P 1 P 1 * C 1 * What about supply? It is simple (although capital accumulation is not simple) -- as P 1 increases, the increase induces firms to produce more, since the yield from doing so is now greater --- P 1 is probably < 1

The equilibrium price of future goods P 1 * = 1/(1+r) So as P 1 * 0 If P 1 * = 0.9, then r is approximately 0.11 or 11%

Rate of return, real rate, and nominal rate R = nominal rate 1+ R = (1 + r)(1 + P ε ), where P ε = increase in overall prices or the inflation rate A lender here, would expect to be compensated for both the opportunity cost of not investing at rate, r, and for the general rise in prices, P ε

What this means is that: 1+R = 1 + r + P ε + r P ε If r P ε is small, then R = r + P ε If the real rate, r, is 0.04 (4%) and expected inflation is 0.10 (10%), then the nominal rate R = = 0.14 or 14%