Limit pricing, entry deterrence and predatory pricing Chapters 12-13.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Perfect Competition 12.
Advertisements

ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 9 office: LUMS C85.
office hours: 8:00AM – 8:50AM tuesdays LUMS C85
Oligopoly Games An Oligopoly Price-Fixing Game
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Cournot versus Stackelberg n Cournot duopoly (simultaneous quantity competition) n Stackelberg duopoly (sequential quantity competition) x2x2 x1x1 x1x2x1x2.
1 Industrial Organization Entry deterrence Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester Week 5.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
12 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Monopoly.
1 Deter Entry. 2 Here we see a model of deterring entry by an existing monopoly firm. We will also introduce the notion of a sequential, or dynamic, game.
1. Credible commitments 2. Preemption 3. Predation 4. Taxonomy of strategic commitments 5. Some Examples of Entry Deterrence Lecture 5: Strategic commitment.
Predatory Conduct What is predatory conduct?
Source: Perloff. Some parts: © 2004 Pearson Addison- Wesley. All rights reserved Strategy Perloff: Chapter 14.
Simultaneous games with continuous strategies Suppose two players have to choose a number between 0 and 100. They can choose any real number (i.e. any.
14 Perfect Competition CHAPTER Notes and teaching tips: 4, 7, 8, 9, 25, 26, 27, and 28. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand”
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Lecture 2: Porter’s Five Forces ©2009 by Marvin Lieberman How Competition Shapes the Creation and Distribution of Economic Value Introduction to Business.
Chapter 11 Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers.
Objectives © Pearson Education, 2005 Oligopoly LUBS1940: Topic 7.
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition
Predatory Conduct What is predatory conduct? –Any strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. –Primary objective of.
Chapter Fourteen Strategy. © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.14–2 Strategic Behavior A set of actions a firm takes to increase its profit,
Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence
Chapter 10 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers. Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially –one firm makes a move new product advertising.
Chapter 14 Firms in competitive Markets
CHAPTER 16 Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation.
Imperfect Competition and Market Power: Core Concepts Defining Industry Boundaries Barriers to Entry Price: The Fourth Decision Variable Price and Output.
13 PART 5 Perfect Competition
1 Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition Entry deterrence I Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester 2012 Week 6.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 Competitive Markets.
Lecture 10: The Theory of Competitive Supply
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Economics 2010 Lecture 12 Perfect Competition. Competition  Perfect Competition  Firms Choices in Perfect Competition  The Firm’s Short-Run Decision.
Dynamic Games & The Extensive Form
Monopolistic Competition Large number of firms producing differentiated products By differentiating its product from its competitors’ products, the firm.
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION. Objectives  Define and identify monopolistic competition  Explain how output and price are determined in a monopolistically.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 6. Competition Prof. Vera Adamchik.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
A monopolistically competitive market is characterized by three attributes: many firms, differentiated products, and free entry. The equilibrium in a monopolistically.
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 13A. After studying this chapter you will be able to Define and identify monopolistic competition Explain how output.
Chapter 13: Predatory Conduct: recent developments 1 Predatory Conduct: Recent Developments.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 10 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly.
The Economics of Organisations and Strategy. Chapter 10 The Dominant Firm and Predation.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Chapter 22: The Competitive Firm Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain a perfectly.
Dynamic games, Stackelburg Cournot and Bertrand
Entry and Exit New firm (Bill Porter develops E*TRADE) Diversifying firm (Microsoft offers Internet Browsers)
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Perfect Competition ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Econ 545, Spring 2016 Industrial Organization Dynamic Games.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Shane Murphy ECON 102 Tutorial: Week 9 Shane Murphy
ECON 330 Lecture 21 Monday, December 9.
Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 9
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence 1 Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence.
ECON 330 Lecture 23 Thursday, December 13.
ECON 4100: Industrial Organization
Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence
Dynamic games and First and Second Movers (The Stackelberg Model)
Entry Deterrence and Predation
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence
Presentation transcript:

Limit pricing, entry deterrence and predatory pricing Chapters 12-13

Limiting entry In markets where firms receive positive profits, we would expect that over time new firms would attempt to enter the industry in order to capture some of these profits. As we have seen in many previous models, in general the more firms are in a given industry, the lower are profits for industry members. New entrants reduce the market power of incumbents and reduce the ability of incumbents to maintain collusion. Now we consider what kinds of actions a firm might take in order to try to deter or prevent entry, either through pricing or through other strategic activities. Such actions are also generally illegal, as they breach the Sherman act makes it illegal to “monopolize or attempt to monopolize… any part of the trade or commerce.”

Stylized facts of Firm Dynamics Entry is common. Dunne, Roberts, Samuelson (1988, 89) find annual entry rates ~8-10% for 2-digit SIC codes over Gerowski (1995) finds % annual entry rates for for 3-digit manufacturing industries in the UK. Jarmin et al (2004) show entry rates in the retail sector of over 60% (especially during economic prosperity). Most entry is by small-scale firms. DRS: entrant market share % (over 5 years). Gerowksi market share %. Cable and Scwalbach (1991): in the US, entrants constitute 7.7% of firms but only 3.2% of output.

Survival rates are low. DRS find 61.5% of entrants exit within 5 years, 79.6% within 10 years. Jarmin et al 59-82% exit rates. Birch (1987) US data, 50% of entrants fail within 5 years. Exit and entry rates vary across industries, but industries with high entry rates also have high exit rates. Very highly correlated. This is in contrast to a view where industries with entry are those that are highly profitable and those with exits are suffering losses. Maybe due to variation in entry costs across industries? So, when thinking about industries, these are not fixed equilibria that remain stable over time; the business environment is very dynamic. Industries can have a “revolving door” of small, new entrants, most of whom fail.

Predatory conduct Strategies that are designed to deter rivals from competing in a market are called “predatory conduct”. A firm engaging in such conduct wants to influence the behavior of rivals, either those currently in the market or those thinking of entering it. Predatory conduct must be credible to be effective. For example, let us return to our simple game of entry that we considered in Lecture 9. (Challenger enters or stays out, incumbent fights or accommodates, payoffs are 1,2 from staying out, 0,0 from fighting entry, 2,1 from accommodating entry). Here, a threat to fight entry is non-credible. What if the game is repeated a (finite) number of times? Can we use a tough reputation effect to deter entry?

The Chain Store Paradox Suppose that the simple entry game is repeated N times, in N separate markets. The incumbent is the same in every market (it is a chain store) while each entrant is a separate firm. So the incumbent cares about the sum of its payoffs across all N markets, while each entrant cares only about their payoff in that market. We might think that we can create a “tough-guy” reputation by fighting early entrants in order to deter entry in later markets. But this strategy unravels. Consider the Nth market. The only rational strategy in that market is to accommodate, because there are no future entrants to deter. Knowing this, the entrant in the Nth market will enter. So, there is no point in fighting in the N-1 th market, because we know that the N-market entrant will enter anyway. So the N-1 entrant will enter. We can use this logic recursively all the way back to the initial market. The unique subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is for all entrants to enter and to be accommodated. In some sense this is a weakness of subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, and in some sense this is a weakness of the model; we need to consider other entry models in order to effectively describe (credible) entry deterrence strategies.

Predatory and limit pricing Predatory pricing is a form of predatory conduct used to try to force current firms to exit. By “irrationally” lowering their prices in the short-term (to a level below long-run average costs, and possibly even below short-run marginal cost) firms seek to force their rivals to receive negative profits, and to exit the industry. This is only rational if the firm can recoup its short term losses later by exploiting its market power. This requires that there are entry costs or entry barriers, otherwise the rival could simply re-enter the market in the future. A similar strategy can be used to deter entry. Keeping prices lower than they would otherwise be could deter entrants from entering the market – this is known as limit pricing. Courts and policy-makers have traditionally been much more concerned with predatory pricing than limit pricing, partly because there is a clear victim in predatory pricing, whereas it is harder to prove a victim in limit pricing. These strategies typically require; it might be possible for a large firm to muscle out a small rival in this way, but it is much more likely to be optimal to accommodate an equally sized rival.

Informal model of entry deterrence Consider a simple variant to the Stackelburg Cournot model. So this is more properly a “limit quantity” model rather than a limit pricing quantity. The incument is the Stackelburg leader. The entrant makes the assumption that whatever its quantity choice is, it will not alter the leader’s choice of output; the leader only gets to choose its quantity once, and it must be able to credibly commit to this level. We must also assume that the entrant’s average cost declines over at least the initial range of low levels of production. When both these assumptions hold, then the incumbent can manipulate the entrant’s profit calculation and discourage entry.

Consider figure 12.1 on page 270. To deter entry, the incumbent must produce the quantity. If the entrant stays out, this implies a market price = What if the entrant now produced any positive output? Because the entrant believes that the incumbent will maintain Q_, the demand faced by the entrant at any price P is the total quantity demand at that price Q(P) minus. The entrant faces a residual demand curve R e. Corresponding to this demand curve is the entrant’s residual marginal revenue curve MR e. The entrant maximizes profit by selecting output q e, at which marginal revenue is just equal to marginal cost. As shown, this is output where (with from the incumbent) the market price will be P 0, and this price is exactly equal to the entrant’s average cost. So, if the incumbent entered, the highest profit it will get is zero. By producing (or any higher quantity) the incumbent is able to deter entry. If there were fixed entry costs, then it becomes even easier to deter entry, because we need only push entrant profits down to the entry costs, rather than down to zero.

For this type of predation to be successful, it is crucial that the entrant believes the incumbent is truly committed to its action; the strategy must be subgame perfect. The incumbent must be able to commit to producing even if the entrant actually enters the market and produces a positive quantity. Though this sounds plausible and may be true, we need to think about a more formal mechanism as to how this might work. One possibility is that it is very costly for firms to adjust their output level. Another possibility is that output level is a function of a physical capacity level, which is a product of capital investment decisions that take some time and cost to adjust.

Capacity expansion as entry- deterring commitment (Dixit 1980) Consider a dynamic, 2-stage game of capacity expansion. In the first stage, the incumbent moves first and chooses a capacity level at a cost of. This capacity is measured in terms of output, and the cost r is the constant cost of 1 unit of capacity. By investing in capacity, the incumbent firm has the capability of producing any output less than or equal to in the second stage of the game; the incumbent’s capacity can be further increased in the second stage, but it cannot be reduced. (Imagine that capacity expansion costs are sunk.) The entrant observes the incumbent’s choice of capacity in stage one, then in stage 2 makes its entry decision. If entry occurs, the two firms choose capacity levels K 1 and K 2, and then play a simultaneous Cournot game in output. The incumbent cannot choose K 1 K 1 or q 2 > K 2.

Market demand is P = A – B(q 1 + q 2 ). Denote any sunk costs incurred by the incumbent (other than those associated with capacity choice as F 1. Each unit of output has a constant marginal cost w. Each unit of capacity costs r per unit. (So in the second round the incumbent pays r(K 1 - ) for capacity. So, in round 2, the incumbent faces: C 1 (q 1,q 2 ; )= F 1 + wq 1 + for q 1 ≤ = F 1 + (w + r)q 1 for q 1 > The only difference between the incumbent and the entrant is that the entrant cannot invest in capacity in stage 1. The entrant faces: C 2 (q 2 ; )= F 2 + (w + r)q 2 Note that the firms face different marginal costs in stage 2 of the game, and so they face different marginal incentives. As long as it is below capacity, the incumbent firm faces a lower marginal cost and so is more willing to increase its output. Thus, investing in capacity can serve as a credible device for the incumbent to commit to producing a higher output level.

We solve this dynamic game by working out what happens in the last stage of the game, in order to then work out the incumbent’s optimal move in the first stage. In stage 2, the firms are playing a Cournot game in quantities. Incumbent firm profits will be: π 1 (q 1,q 2; ) = [A – B(q 1 + q 2 )]q 1 – [wq 1 – F 1 ] for q 1 ≤ π 1 (q 1,q 2; ) = [A – B(q 1 + q 2 )]q 1 – [(w+r)q 1 – F 1 ] for q 1 > We can see that marginal revenue for the incumbent from increasing q 1 is always MR 1 = A – 2Bq 1 – Bq 2. Marginal cost will change depending on whether or not the firm decides to add capacity: it is either w or r depending on whether or not it adds capacity. Accordingly, we get two separate results from setting MR = MC, and so two separate best response functions: q 1 * = (A – w)/2B – q 2 /2when q 1 * ≤ q 1 * = (A – w – r)/2B – q 2 /2when q 1 * >

This means that the incumbent firm’s best response function jumps at the output level q 1 * =, whereas the entrant firm’s does not. The entrant firm profits will be: π 2 (q 1,q 2; ) = [A – B(q 1 + q 2 )]q 2 – [(w+r)q 2 – F 2 ] This gives a best response function: q 2 * = (A – w – r)/2B – q 1 /2 Note that this is the entrant’s best response given that it chooses to produce a positive level of output. This does not take into account the sunk costs F 2 that the potential entrant incurs should it actually decide to enter. Note that (A – w – r)/2B is the quantity that the entrant would produce if the incumbent chose q 1 = 0. At this quantity, the entrant will make a positive profit. As q 1 increases, the optimal q 2 will decline, and the entrant’s profits will decline, eventually to the point where profits are exactly zero, and then go negative. At this point, the best response function jumps, and the entrant should stay out of the market entirely and get profits of zero.

Understanding how this works, the incumbent in the first round knows that they can use to manipulate this. The incumbent will choose to give itself the maximum profit possible in stage 2, which might be to commit to a large enough quantity so that the entrant will stay out. We will not solve the model in full in class; look through chapter 12 in the text to see the full solution. What the solution shows is that (depending on the particular parameters) entry may well not occur, either because a) the entrant’s costs are so high that it cannot profitably enter even if the incumbent acts nonstrategically as a monopolist or b) entry might otherwise be profitable except that the incumbent acts strategically and deters entry by investing in enough capacity to produce beyond the output of a pure monopoly.

If entry cannot be deterred, the incumbent can still act as a Stackelburg leader. If entry can be deterred, the incumbent can do even better. The incumbent’s advantage comes from its ability to commit credibly to a particular output level in stage 2 by means of its choice of capacity in stage 1. Effectively, the incumbent commits to producing at least as much as the initial capacity it installs, because to produce any less amounts to throwing away some of that investment, which is costly. The incumbent can sometimes deter entry by deliberately over- investing in capacity – ie investing in capacity that would not be profitable were it not for the fact that doing so eliminates the competition. So such capacity expansion is predatory. Note also that the capacity expansion is credible as a deterrent strategy only to the extent that the capacity, one in place, is a sunk cost. If capacity was not sunk, then over-investment would not be credible, since it could be undone, and the game would revert to Cournot. The incumbent is gaining strategic advantage by deliberately tying their hands and modifying their stage 2 incentives.