Gießen, 03.12.2009 Chapter 4: Increasing returns to scale 4.1 Empirical observations 4.2 Homogeneous products 4.2.1 External economies of scale 4.2.2 Contestable.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
INTRA-INDUSTRY TRADE AND THE SCALE EFFECTS OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION Elisa Riihimäki Statistics Finland, Business Structures September
Advertisements

Chapter 8: Competitive Firms and Markets We learned firms production and cost functions. In this chapter, we study how firms use those information to reach.
PAUL.S.CALEM DANIEL.F.SPULBER.   This paper examines two part pricing by a multiproduct monopoly and a differentiated oligopoly.  Two part pricing.
Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - What is the old empirical IO? The old empirical IO refers to studies that.
The Gains from Trade: A General Equilibrium View Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference–the one takes account of the.
International Economics Tenth Edition
2. Free Trade and Protection. Summary 1.Theory of Comparative Advantage: Why trade is good. 2.Where comparative advantage comes from: Heckscher-Ohlin.
CHAPTER 9; IMPERFECT COMPETITION
The role of the firm Chapter 4. Trade and Imperfect Competition Intra-industry trade Relevance to international business –MNEs and assumption of imperfect.
Chapter 3 Modern Trade Theories
1 CHAPTER 1: PRO-COMPETITVE EFFECT OF TRADE 1A: Imports as market discipline 1B: Empirical evidence 1C: Heterogeneity of firms, productivity, mark-ups.
6 Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition 1
Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade
General Equilibrium Theory
Market size and tax competition Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano, Tanguy van Ypersele.
Imperfect Competition, Increasing Returns, and Product Variety
Economies of Scale Economies of Scale make it advantageous for each country to specialize in the production of only limited number of goods & services.
Goods Prices and Factor Prices: The Distributional Consequences of International Trade Nothing is accomplished until someone sells something. (popular.
1 BA 187 – International Trade Specific Factors & Differential Gains from Trade.
Equilibrium in a Monopolistically Competitive Market
The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Theorem
For a long time we were happy with the old trade theory featuring comparative advantage and its more modern trade theorems.
Sources of Comparative Advantage
The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Theorem
Trade Under Increasing Returns to Scale
HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY  What determines comparative advantage?  What are the effects of international trade on the earnings of factors of production?
Robinson Crusoe model 1 consumer & 1 producer & 2 goods & 1 factor: –two price-taking economic agents –two goods: the labor (or leisure x 1 ) of the consumer.
1 Comparative advantage: A basic example Productivities Endowments (here, labor forces) WineDrape Portugal845 UK1220 Assumptions Two countries (Portugal.
Factor Endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theory
An Introduction to International Economics
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
Prof. Dr. Volker Clausen Universität Duisburg-Essen Campus Essen 1 Ricardo, David (1817): On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London.
Trade: Factor Availability and Factor Proportions Are Key
Chapter II: Comparative Advantage_David Ricado Lectured by: Mr. SOK Chanrithy.
1 LECTURE #14: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 16 (Chapter 17 in 4 th Edition) Monopolistic Competition.
The Gains from Trade: A General Equilibrium View Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference–the one takes account of the.
Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade
New Classical Theories of International Trade
1 CHAPTER 1: PRO-COMPETITVE EFFECT OF TRADE 1A: Imports as market discipline 1B: Empirical evidence 1C: Heterogeneity of firms, productivity, mark-ups.
Unit 1: Trade Theory Heckscher-Ohlin Model 2/3/2012.
Chapter 2 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model International Economics: Theory and Policy International Economics: Theory.
1 Competition Among the Big and the Small Ken-Ichi Shimomura and Jacques-François Thisse.
Gießen, Differentiated products Vertical differentiation: different qualities Horizontal differentiation: equal qualities, but consumers.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2012 The McGraw-Hill Companies, All Rights Reserved Chapter 6: Scale Economies, Imperfect Competition, and Trade.
International Trade and Finance for Global Logistics MAGL 570 Fall 2010 Steven Yamarik
Competitors and Competition
© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 7 Imperfect Competition, Increasing Returns, and Product Variety.
International Economics Tenth Edition
A2 Economics International Trade A2 Economics Presentation 2006.
International Economics Tenth Edition
EF310: International Trade and Business Lecture 17 Theories of International Trade.
International Economics Tenth Edition
Economies of Scale Introduction and appropriation issues.
External economies of scale Introduction and appropriation issues.
The “New Trade Theory” + some other post-HO-models Appleyard & Field (& Cobb): Chapter 10 Krugman & Obstfeld: Chapter 6.
Chapter 9 Oligopoly and Firm Architecture
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE
Study Unit 4.
International Trade Trade patterns and trade politics
Factor Endowments Theory and Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Chapter 1: Two-Sector Models
International Economics Tenth Edition
Chapter 5: Alternative Theories of Trade
Chapter 6: Alternative Theories of Trade
International Trade and Economic Growth
Production Possibilities Schedules
6. Strategic Export Policy
Industrial Structure and Capital Flows Author: Keyu Jin Present by:
Presentation transcript:

Gießen, Chapter 4: Increasing returns to scale 4.1 Empirical observations 4.2 Homogeneous products External economies of scale Contestable markets Oligopolies 4.3 Differentiated products Love of variety Ideal variety

4.1 Empirical observations  Volume of trade largest between „similar“ countries within OECD (more than 50% of world trade).  Substantial intra-industrial trade (more than 25%)  Trade grows faster than world income  Growing importance of transactions within multi- national corporations  Trade liberalization and free trade associations should have led to a restructuring of production and changes in factor income – not observed, all factor incomes grow at the same pace. Gießen,

4.2 Homogeneous products External economies of scale Production function of representative firm: x i = f(v i,  ) (1) where  denotes the positive external effects which are beyond the control of firm i (e.g. domestic output of the commodity, world output, total domestic income etc.) Gießen,

Justifications:  Cheaper inputs for larger industries (however, begs the question of where cheaper inputs come from)  Approximation of model with price equal to average cost in equilibrium (however, compare to contestable markets)  Technical progress cannot be appropriated (however, begs the question where it comes from).  Learning by doing – larger well trained labor force. Gießen,

Autarky equilibrium Unit cost function: b j = b j (w,  ), b j  < 0, b j w = a j. a j = (a 1j,…,a ij,…a Mj ) = vector of inputs per unit of output of good j. Equilibrium conditions: p a = b(w a,  a ) (2) v = Ax a (3) Trade equilibrium p  b(w,  ) (4) v = Ax (5) Gießen,

Welfare gains from trade: Graham (1923): Free trade may reduce welfare through reallocation of resources from industries with scale economies to those without. Kemp and Negishi (1970): Reallocation in opposite direction ensures gains from trade. Helpman and Krugman (1985): Sufficient condition for gains from trade:  p j f j (v j a,  )   p j f j (v j a,  a ),(6) i.e. at world market prices „on average“ factor productivity is greater than in autarky, given the factor allocation of autarky and  instead of  a. Gießen,

Proof: Idea: Show that (6) implies feasibility of c a = x a in the free trade equilibrium, then apply WARP: px a   p j f j (v j a,  )  G(p,v,  ) = GDP-function. Alternative sufficient condition for gains from trade:  b j (w,  a )x j a   b j (w,  )x j a (7) i.e. at world market prices costs of production of autarky outputs are smaller in the free trade equilibrium than in the autarky equilibrium. The proof is similar to the one above: Gießen,

Proof: (4) and (7) imply px a   b j (w,  )x j a   b j (w,  a )x j a, and by definition b j (w,  a ) = wa j (w,  a )  wa j (w a,  a ), hence px a   wa j (w a,  )x j a = w  a j (w a,  )x j a = vw = G(p,v,  ), Thus x a = c a is feasible in the free trade equilibrium which cannot be inferior to the autarky equilibrium. Gießen,

Trade structure In addition to different technologies (Ricardo) and/or different factor endowments (Heckscher-Ohlin) different utilization of economies of scale as cause of comparative advantage: Predictions about trade structure become even more difficult. Sufficient condition for traditional results to hold: external effects are the same for all countries in the free trade equilibrium. Gießen,

Examples: a) Ricardo: Production functions: f j (v j,  ) =  j (  )v j /a j, F j (V j,  ) =  j (  )V j /A j (8) The domestic country will export good one if a 1 /a 2 < A 1 /A 2. This does not rule out the possibility that in autarky we get [  2 (  a )a 1 ]/[  1 (  a )a 2 ] > [  2 (  A )A 1 ]/[  1 (  A )A 2 ], hence predictions about trade patterns may not be possible by using only information about autarky. Gießen,

b) Heckscher-Ohlin All countries have identical production functions: x j = f j (v j,  ) (9) i.e. external effects are the same and have the same effects in all countries in the free trade equilibrium – predictions about trade patterns using information after trade takes place are possible. c) Counterexample: sector- and country-specific externalities: x j = x j a v j /a j (10) Firm perceives infinite costs without domestic production. Gießen,

Factor price equalization: Approach: determination of FPE-set (allocations of factor endowments between countries which allow replication of integrated equilibrium through free trade equilibria). Focus on country- and sector specific external scale economies – assumed to exist for subset I E of all goods. Their production functions are x i = f i (v i,x i ), i  I E (11) Subset of goods produced with constant returns to scale: I C. Gießen,

Integrated equilibrium conditions: p i = b i (w,x i ) (12) v i =  a ji (w,x i )x i (13) where v i denotes the vector of factor inputs in industry i and a ji is the input of factor j per unit of output of industry i. The set of all factor allocations compatible with FPE (denoted as  ) is defined analogously to the standard case with the additional requirement that the integrated equilibrium output of goods with increasing returns to scale can be produced in one country: Gießen,

 = {v 1,...,v J |  ij  0,  j ij =1  i  I, ij  {0,1}  i  I E } v j =  i ij v i  i  J (14) where ij denotes the share of country j of the vector of factor inputs in industry i in the integrated equilibrium, and v j denotes the vector of factor endowments of country j. For two countries and three industries, one of which has external economies of scale, the set  is shown in figure 4.1. Gießen,

Figure 4.1 FPE-set for industry 1 being capital intensive and enjoying increasing returns to scale.

Remarks:  The diagonal need not belong to .  The equilibrium is not unique with respect to the structure of production.  Increasing returns to scale will generate division of labor and trade even between identical countries.  It need not be the relatively capital rich country that produces the capital intensive good, absolute size also matters.  Net factor import is uniquely determined. Gießen,

Figure 4.2: Indeterminacy with respect to the location of industry 1

Non-uniqueness Integrated economy, two goods, one factor, production function x 1 = x 1  v 1 /a 1. Let v = 1,v 1 < 1/2. The following figure (4.3) shows  for this case: 0  ___________Q__________Q‘___________  0* v h measured from left to right. Let 0Q = Q‘0* = v 1. v h between Q and Q‘: integrated equilibrium is reproduced, location of industry 1 indeterminate. v h < v 1 : integrated equilibrium reproduced if industry 1 is in foreign country. Second equ.: Industry 1 in home country, foreign country firms perceive infinite production costs. Gießen,

Non-uniqueness cont’d Let v 1 > 1/2.  is shown in figure (4.3): 0  ___________Q’_ _ _ _ _ _Q___________  0*  consists of the solid lines 0Q‘ and Q0*.  v h between Q‘Q: integrated equilibrium cannot be reproduced.  v h in 0Q‘: integrated equilibrium reproduced, industry 1 in foreign country.  Industry 1 in home country: no FPE.  Both countries produce good 1: FPE, but no reproduction of integrated world equilibrium. Gießen,

4.2.2 Contestable markets Extension of Bertrand model to industries with sub- additive cost-functions: c(  x i ) <  c(x i ) Reasons: Economies of scale, fixed costs. Crucial assumptions: no sunk costs, no entry or exit costs. Dasgupta-Stiglitz: Theory well funded, but not well founded. Main difference to previous model: scale economies are internal for firms and known to them. Gießen,

Integrated world equilibrium: additional condition: c i (w,x i (p i ))  p i  p i < p i * rules out „inefficient“ equilibria (see Figure 4.5 below)

Sufficient condition for gains from trade:  c i (w,x i )x i a   c i (w,x i a )x i a Non-existence of free trade equilibrium: Integrated economy, two goods, one factor, production function x 1 = x 1  v 1 /a 1. Let v = 1,v 1 < 1/2. The following figure (4.6) shows  for this case: 0  ___________Q__________Q‘___________  0* v h measured from left to right. Let 0Q = Q‘0* = v 1. v h between Q and Q‘: w greater in country that produces good 1  provokes entry from other country, but two firms cannot co-exist in a contestable market. Gießen,

4.2.3 Oligopolies One-shot Cournot-model  Market concentration and trade: Even if two countries are identical, free trade increases competitive pressure and lowers prices as compared to autarky  Oligopoly and transport costs: may lead to asymmetric oligopoly in each country, but above effect still possible. Gießen,

Concentration in partial equilibrium k identical consumers, n firms, market demand: X(p) = kx(p). Firm i maximizes  i (x i ) = x i p([  j  i x j + x i ]/k) – c(w,x i ), (15) FOCs: p + p‘x i /k = c x (w,x i ) (16) Identical firms  x i = kx(p)/n Elasticity of demand of representative consumer:  = - x‘(p)p/x Gießen,

Substituting this into (16) yields p[1 – 1/n  (p)] = c x (w,kx(p)/n) = pR -1 (17) Suppose there is free trade between two perfectly identical countries (same number of identical consumers and firms). Instead of (17) we get p[1 – 1/2n  (p)] = c x (w,kx(p)/n) (18) i.e. the price goes down even though no commodity flows will be observed. Sufficient condition for gains from trade: output in oligopolistic industries grows (pro-competitive effect of trade). Gießen,

The direction of trade Depends not only on costs and on pre-trade prices, but also on the number of firms and consumers:  Identical countries except for the number of firms: country with larger number of firms exports (but also had lower pre-trade price).  Identical costs, but different number of firms and consumers: net exporter is country with larger firms/consumers ratio.  Identical countries except for costs: country with smaller costs is net exporter. Gießen,

In general no clear prediction on the basis of only one variable possible: cost advantages may be over- compensated by market size, etc. Reason: Less efficient firms may still be active in a Cournot-equilibrium. Gießen,

General equilibrium trade patterns Equilibrium condition for a Cournot-oligopoly: p[1 – 1/n  (p)] = c x (w,kx(p)/n) = pR -1 (17) implying R = [1 – 1/n  (p)] -1 (19) “Wedge” between price and marginal cost: 1 − R -1 Let R i denote the „mark-up” perceived by firm i. Constant returns to scale imply that resources are allocated s.t.  R i -1 p i x i is maximized (Helpman 1984). Gießen,

Factor abundancy: If all firms in a country perceive the same R i then differences in output will depend solely on differences in supply functions, hence with identical production functions on differences in factor endowments. R i ‘s most likely to be identical across countries with factor price equality. Gießen,

Factor price equalization Integrated world economy: Two types of industries: I o oligopolies, I c competitive industries. Equilibrium conditions:  := c x x/c….elasticity of costs, measure for increasing returns to scale.  := 1/  =  c/c x,  c = average cost. Consequently, pR -1 = c x can be written as pR -1 =  c/ . Gießen,

Collecting terms, the equilibrium conditions are A(w)x c + A(w)x O = v Factor price equalization (and reproduction of integrated world equilibrium) requires that factor allocation is compatible with number of firms of the oligopoly in each country.

Gießen,

Figure 4.7: FPE-set, industry 1: oligopoly, industries 2 and 3: competitive.

Gießen, Net import of all factors‘s services: possible for a country with a large share in oligopolistic industries. Suppose s j (share of country j in world GDP) satisfies s j > v 1 j /v 1 =...= v N j /v N i.e. share in world GDP is greater than share in factor endowments: possible due to profits.

Gießen, Figure 4.8: capital rich country exports embodied capital services and imports embodied labor services. C’: share in factor income, C”: share in world GDP.

Gießen, Figure 4.9: capital rich country imports embodied capital services and embodied labor services. C’: share in factor income, C”: share in world GDP.

Market segmentation Introduction of transport costs t: Example: two identical countries, each with one firm. Home market: 2 firms, asymmetric Cournot model: domestic firm has marginal costs c, foreign firm has marginal costs c + t. Equilibrium conditions: p(x d + x f ) + x d p‘(x d + x f ) = c, p(x d + x f ) + x f p‘(x d + x f ) = c + t. Equilibrium with x d > x f > 0 exists for t < p m – c. p m = monopoly price. Gießen,

Welfare effects: w = u(x d + x f ) – c(x d + x f ) – tx f dw = u’(x d + x f )(dx d + dx f ) – c(dx d + dx f ) – tdx f – dtx f Normalize u(x) s.t. u‘(x) = p: dw = (p – c – t)(dx d + dx f ) + tdx d – dtx f Note that dt < 0  dx d < 0 < dx f 1.x f dt...cost reduction  w , but x f = 0 if t = p m – c. 2.(p – c – t)(dx d +dx f )  w  (export increase), but 0 if t = p m – c. 3.tdx d...  w  (replacement of domestic shipments through exports). dw/dt > 0 at t  p – c.

Gießen, Figure 4.10: Gains and losses due to changes of t.