The economics of forest management National and international forest policy
Why manage forests? Manage deforestation Global forest down 40% since pre-ag times. Tropical deforestation: Forest Benefits--Biodiversity, carbon sequestration Often “commons” issue – incomplete property rights Losses: 130,000 km 2 per year (200x200 miles) Temperate deforestation Biodiversity loss Habitat for endangered species (NW Spotted Owl) Timber supply Often publicly owned, privately harvested – mismatch of incentives
Forest management policies — attempt to account for external benefits of forests Common policies Subsidies, taxes, technology standards, silvicultural practice regulations. Relatively new policies Forest certification, carbon offsets, property rights
Subsidies Free seedlings, management assistance, financial aid – common in developing world Tradeoff often between forest and agriculture Success depends on relative prices of forest vs. agricultural products Developing world: Collection of wood for fuel a major problem. Some success with subsidies for woodlots.
Taxes Used on private forestland to Capture scarcity rent for gov’t and/or Correct for externalities Monitoring & information problems pose challenges, especially in developing world Statistics on harvested timber underestimates High-grading can result
Regulations Government may dictate silvicultural method Seed-tree, shade-tree, even aged, clear-cut Regulations mitigate environmental harm Buffer strips, wood in streams, structured canopy, reforestation requirements, road stipulations
Forest concessions Federally-owned forests (e.g. Nat’l Forest in US) grant concessions to private forestry companies. Typically auction off right to harvest a certain tract of forest, may be corrupt. Fees usually not market value (unless auction) Property rights problem – no incentive to care for land since don’t own it. May require environmental bond.
Forest certification A form of “green labeling” Provides information to consumers Consumers will be paying for a public good Internationally-recognized certifiers Forest Stewardship Council Certified 30 million hectares in 56 countries Acts like distinct (substitute) market
Carbon offsets Financial incentives to increase storage of carbon by keeping trees in ground, reforesting, or planting high C-sequestering species. Problem: usually ignores biodiversity considerations (e.g. native vs. exotic fast growth) Several global carbon payment funds to which countries can apply. Hard to verify what country would have done Called the “counterfactual”
Enhanced property rights Most countries: state is largest forest landowner Problems: monitoring, ignorant of local needs, poor revenue collection, poaching (open access), limited info Problems when gov’t takes over from community management – ignores local customs and laws Property rights can be shared with locals “Panchayat forestry” (Nepal), “joint forest management” (India), “community-based” forestry (Philippines, others), “communal tenure” (advocated by World Bank). Combination with other instruments (e.g. taxes)
US Nat’l Forests & Grasslands
Public forest management (US) USFS: 156 Nat’l Forests, 194 million acres Concessions: terms of contract affect Rotation interval, nature of harvest, non-timber values, depletion of forest Pricing of concessions Often p < market value, sometimes p < mc Infrastructure (roads) often provided free (1) few buyers, (2) external costs ignored Tenure length < rotation interval Why is this important?
A biological model Managing tract of trees of certain age (all the same age). Choose rotation interval (how long before cutting) to maximize total volume per unit time (max sustainable yield)? V(t) = volume of wood at age t. Harvest at time T and start process again What should be T?
Shape of V(t) Vol. V(t) Time, t
Alternatively Time, t Change in Volume, dV(t)/dt Look Familiar?
Simplest model: pick rotation to maximize average annual forest growth Problem: max T Q(T)/T Solution: (TQ’ – Q)/T 2 = 0 Q(T)/T = Q’(T) Average growth rate = marginal growth Not quite right since we have neglected discounting: payoff 50 years from now not the same as today.
Graphically Vol. Q(t) Time, t T1T1 Q(t) Average growth at time T 1 is slope of line from origin to Q(T 1 ) Marginal growth at time T 1 is slope of Q(t) at time T 1 Q(T*)/T* = Q’(T*) T*
A bio-economic model Incorporate: price, harvest cost, discounting. p = price per MBF, c = cost per MBF, r=discount rate (p-c) = rent Since trees grow continuously, we’ll discount continuously: 1/(1+r) t e -rt max T (p-c)Q(T)e -rT Harvest when rent peaks
Result of bio-economic model Take derivative, set = 0. T* is place where % growth rate equal discount rate: Q’(T*)/Q(T*) = r “Harvest when tree growth rate equals rate of growth of next best alternative”. Think of trees as money in the bank: when bank payoff drops below interest rate, withdraw your money.
Extensions of this model Can include Multiple rotations Replanting costs Non-timber values of forest (water, recreation, biodiversity, etc.) Extended models will allow us to analyze different economic policies (e.g. tax, site fees, license fees, etc.)