A New Simple Square Root Option Pricing Model Antonio Camara & Yaw-Huei Wang Yaw-Huei Wang Associate Professor Department of Finance National Taiwan University.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Ordinary least Squares
Advertisements

Appendix 27A: An Alternative Method to Derive The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model (Related to 27.5) By Cheng Few Lee Joseph Finnerty John Lee Alice.
Option Valuation The Black-Scholes-Merton Option Pricing Model
COMM 472: Quantitative Analysis of Financial Decisions
Arvid Kjellberg- Jakub Lawik - Juan Mojica - Xiaodong Xu.
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull The Black-Scholes- Merton Model Chapter 13.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model.
Options Week 7. What is a derivative asset? Any asset that “derives” its value from another underlying asset is called a derivative asset. The underlying.
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN INVESTMENTS.
MGT 821/ECON 873 Volatility Smiles & Extension of Models
Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing What effect does psychological bias (irrationality) have on asset demands and asset prices?
© 2004 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 6 The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model.
Financial options1 From financial options to real options 2. Financial options Prof. André Farber Solvay Business School ESCP March 10,2000.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
Simple Linear Regression
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
Pricing an Option The Binomial Tree. Review of last class Use of arbitrage pricing: if two portfolios give the same payoff at some future date, then they.
Chapter 6 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
5.1 Option pricing: pre-analytics Lecture Notation c : European call option price p :European put option price S 0 :Stock price today X :Strike.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
Théorie Financière Financial Options Professeur André Farber.
Corporate Finance Options Prof. André Farber SOLVAY BUSINESS SCHOOL UNIVERSITÉ LIBRE DE BRUXELLES.
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
11.1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th Edition © 1999 by John C. Hull The Black-Scholes Model Chapter 11.
BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL Chapters 7 and 8.
1 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model MGT 821/ECON 873 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model.
Advanced Risk Management I Lecture 6 Non-linear portfolios.
Option Valuation. Intrinsic value - profit that could be made if the option was immediately exercised –Call: stock price - exercise price –Put: exercise.
Version 1.2 Copyright © 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to:
Portfolio Management-Learning Objective
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio management Lecture: 24 Course Code: MBF702.
The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black- Scholes Chapter 12.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
HJM Models.
1 The Black-Scholes Model Chapter Pricing an European Call The Black&Scholes model Assumptions: 1.European options. 2.The underlying stock does.
Chapter 10: Options Markets Tuesday March 22, 2011 By Josh Pickrell.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin CHAPTER 18 Option Valuation.
Sponsor: Dr. K.C. Chang Tony Chen Ehsan Esmaeilzadeh Ali Jarvandi Ning Lin Ryan O’Neil Spring 2010.
Black Scholes Option Pricing Model Finance (Derivative Securities) 312 Tuesday, 10 October 2006 Readings: Chapter 12.
A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time Carl Lindberg
Valuing Stock Options: The Black- Scholes Model Chapter 11.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 6.
11.1 Introduction to Futures and Options Markets, 3rd Edition © 1997 by John C. Hull The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black- Scholes Chapter 11.
Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 7th Ed, Ch 13, Copyright © John C. Hull 2010 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter.
Option Pricing Models: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model aka Black – Scholes Option Pricing Model (BSOPM)
Option Valuation.
Comment on “A New Simple Square Root Option Pricing Model” written by Camara and Wang San-Lin Chung Department of Finance National Taiwan University.
13.1 Valuing Stock Options : The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13.
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th International Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter B-S-M model is used to determine the option price of any underlying stock. They believed that stock follow.
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
Chapter 7 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
OPTIONS PRICING AND HEDGING WITH GARCH.THE PRICING KERNEL.HULL AND WHITE.THE PLUG-IN ESTIMATOR AND GARCH GAMMA.ENGLE-MUSTAFA – IMPLIED GARCH.DUAN AND EXTENSIONS.ENGLE.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model 1. The Stock Price Assumption Consider a stock whose price is S In a short period of time of length  t, the.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 The Binomial Solution How do we find a replicating portfolio consisting.
Introduction to Options. Option – Definition An option is a contract that gives the holder the right but not the obligation to buy or sell a defined asset.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Bounds and Prices of Currency Cross-Rate Options
The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black-Scholes Chapter 12
Saif Ullah Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and.
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Simple Linear Regression and Correlation
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
Presentation transcript:

A New Simple Square Root Option Pricing Model Antonio Camara & Yaw-Huei Wang Yaw-Huei Wang Associate Professor Department of Finance National Taiwan University

Introduction  The option pricing model of Black and Scholes (1973) is among the most important works in finance theory.  The theory developed by Black and Scholes (1973) is particularly attractive because it is a complete equilibrium formulation of the problem. the final formula is a function of observable variables, making the model subject to direct empirical tests.  During the last 35 years many empirical tests have been done to the Black-Scholes model and many alternative models have been proposed. Most are difficult to implement.

Introduction (cont.)  In this paper, we introduce the simple square root option pricing model (SSROPM) with a closed-form solution of the Black-Scholes type. Our basic square root option pricing model assumes that the square root of the stock price follows a normal distribution. We price options in a simple general equilibrium economy with a representative agent who has a generalized logarithm utility function, advocated by Rubinstein (1976).  Both SSROPM and the Black-Scholes option pricing formulas are preference-free. We extend the technique of pricing by substitution in equilibrium of Brennan (1979), Stapleton and Subrahmanyam (1984), Camara (2003, 2008), and Schroder (2004).

The Economic model  The model assumes that markets open at the beginning and at the end of the economy and, then, that there is no trade between these two dates.  There is a representative agent who is endowed, at time 0, with the aggregate wealth W 0. The representative agent invests his endowment in both risky assets and riskless assets.  The initial portfolio of risky assets consists of n s shares of stock with a price S 0, n c call options on the stock with strike price K and current price C 0, and n p put options on the stock with strike price K and current price P 0.

The Economic model (cont.)  At the end of the economy, time T, the representative agent ’ s wealth is:  The representative agent maximizes his expected utility of terminal wealth with respect to (n s, n c, n p ) to find his optimal portfolio and equilibrium prices:

The Economic model (cont.)  Solving the first order conditions for current prices of the stock, call, and put yields the following equilibrium pricing relationships:

The Economic model (cont.)  We define, as in Camara (2003), the asset specific pricing kernel as: and use the definition in the previous equations yielding:  In order to evaluate the pricing kernel, we need to make assumptions on the utility function of the representative agent, the distribution of aggregate wealth, and the distribution of the stock price.

The Economic model (cont.)  Define 1. The generalized logarithmic utility function with W T > −A/C. Nonsatiation implies that C > 0. Aggregate preferences are characterized by decreasing proportional risk aversion (DPRA), constant proportional risk aversion (CPRA), or increasing proportional risk aversion (IPRA) if A < 0, A = 0, or A = 0.

The Economic model (cont.)  Definition 2. The displaced lognormal distribution of aggregate wealth Let z w be a standard normal random variable, then aggregate wealth W T has a displaced lognormal distribution defined by: We say that aggregate wealth has a displaced lognormal distribution. W T > −A/C, −1 0 is the volatility of W T.

The Economic model (cont.)  Definition 3. The square root distribution of the stock price Let z s be a standard normal random variable, then the stock price S T has a square root distribution defined by: We say that the stock price has a square root distribution. is the drift, is the volatility, and is the rescale of S T.

The Economic model (cont.)  We assume that z w and z s have correlation ρ, according to definitions 1, 2, and 3, then asset specific pricing kernel is given by: where

The Economic model (cont.)

 Where N( ) is c.d.f and n( ) is p.d.f of a standard normal random variable, K is the strike price, and T the maturity of the option.  It is interesting to observe that these option pricing equations depend neither on the drift of the stock μ nor on any parameter of the utility function or distribution of wealth. In this sense the price formulas are preference-free like the Black-Scholes option pricing model (BSOPM).

Data  The primary data are the daily option prices written on the S&P 500 index (closing mid-quotes) for the period from 1996 to 2005, which are collected from OptionMetrics Ivy DB.  The risk-free interest rates are calculated from linearly interpolating the zero curves formed by a collection of continuously compounded zero-coupon interest rates.  Dividend effect has been got rid of the from the option prices by using the ex-dividend S&P 500 index levels as the underlying asset prices in our model.

Data (cont.)  Only out-of-money options are used since out-of-money options are usually traded more heavily than in-the-money options.  The option prices are filtered using some additional criteria: Firstly, we exclude those option prices that violate any arbitrage-free bounds. Secondly, we exclude prices of options with time-to-maturities less than seven calendar days in order to avoid the liquidity issue imposed on the short-maturity options. Thirdly, we also ignore those options with prices less than 0.5 as these option prices could be insensitive to the information flow.

Empirical Results  Estimation of Parameters With the market prices of (equivalent) call options with the same trading and expiration dates, the three parameters of our SSROPM, α, β, and σ, are estimated for each set of market data by minimizing the following loss function: where C i and c i denote the market and theoretical call prices, respectively, and n is the number of option contracts in the set of market data with different strike prices K i.

Empirical Results (cont.)  Properties of Parameters The parameter α is the minimum price level possible at the expiration day of an option. Hence, the estimates of for medium and long maturities are identical to 0. the α estimates for some very short maturities such as 7 or 8 days can be far from 0, with a maximum as high as β is a rescaling parameter, essentially its value depends on the price level of the underlying asset. Therefore, the estimates are tightly related to the corresponding S&P 500 index levels and show no significant difference across time-to-maturities. σ describes the volatility of the distribution of the underlying asset price at expiration, but essentially it is different from that variation parameter in the Black-Scholes model, σ -BS, although both are volatility measures. The values of σ have no significant difference among the results for different time-to-maturities. See Table 2.

Table 2: Summary statistics of the parameter estimates ParameterStatistics T < 9090 ≤ T ≤ 180T > 180 Total α Mean Std Dev Max Min0.00 β Mean Std Dev Max Min

Table 2: Summary statistics of the parameter estimates (cont.) ParameterStatistics T < 9090 ≤ T ≤ 180T > 180 Total σ Mean Std Dev Max Min σ-BS Mean0.20 Std Dev Max Min

Empirical Results (cont.)  Fitting Errors of Option Prices The price fitting errors are measured by the absolute differences between the theoretical and market prices for the SSROPM and Black-Scholes model respectively. The errors are also measured in terms of the Black-Scholes implied volatility. Regardless of which moenyness and/or time-to-maturity is considered, the price fitting errors of SSROPM are much lower than those of the Black-Scholes model. See Table 3. The results of Wilcoxon ’ s Signed-Rank Test still strongly support the superiority of SSROPM. See Table 4.

Table 3: The summary statistics of fitting errors of option prices and implied volatilities Panel A: Errors of Option Prices Time-to-Maturity Moneyness T < 9090 ≤ T ≤ 180T > 180Total SRBSSRBSSRBSSRBS M < (1.73)(1.96)(2.75)(3.30)(3.52)(4.47)(3.04)(3.85) 0.97 ≤ m ≤ (1.03)(1.08)(1.47)(1.53)(1.98)(2.17)(1.39)(1.50) M > (1.67)(1.81)(2.61)(2.87)(3.45)(4.06)(3.07)(3.64) Total (1.64)(1.82)(2.69)(3.14)(3.51)(4.36)(2.97)(3.66)

Table 3: The summary statistics of fitting errors of option prices and implied volatilities (cont.) Panel B: Errors of Implied Volatility Time-to-Maturity Moneyness T < 9090 ≤ T ≤ 180T > 180Total SRBSSRBSSRBSSRBS M < (0.0501)(0.0551)(0.0453)(0.0540)(0.0341)(0.0430)(0.0452)(0.0515) 0.97 ≤ m ≤ (0.0086)(0.0089)(0.0054)(0.0057)(0.0047)(0.0051)(0.0078)(0.0081) M > (0.0180)(0.0189)(0.0152)(0.0174)(0.0125)(0.0159)(0.0155)(0.0175) Total (0.0449)(0.0494)(0.0410)(0.0490)(0.0300)(0.0382)(0.0399)(0.0460)

Table 4: The results of Wilcoxon ’ s Signed-Rank Test  The null hypothesis: the median of SSROPM errors is equal to or larger than that of the Black-Scholes model  All test statistics are significant under the 1% significance level. Time-to-Maturity Moneyness T<9090≤T≤180T>180Total m< ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 0.97≤m≤ ( ) (-26.30) (-31.77) ( ) m> ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Total ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

Empirical Results (cont.)  Patterns of Implied Volatility Functions We select four horizons, 30, 60, 120, and 240 days, to investigate the patterns of implied volatility functions of the SSROPM and the Black-Scholes model. Firstly, we use the averages of those parameters estimated in the first step as the inputs of the two alternative models. Secondly, we use the parameter averages to compute the theoretical call prices with various strike prices in terms of moneyness defined by the strike price over the forward price. Finally, all theoretical prices are converted into Black-Scholes implied volatilities, which are plotted against their moneynesses for the four different time-to-maturities. See Figure 1.

Figure 1: Black-Scholes implied volatility of fitted option prices ■ : SSROPM ▲ : Black-Scholes Model

Concluding Remarks  Rather than assuming that the logarithm of the stock price follows a normal distribution, e.g. Black-Scholes model, we assume that the square root of the stock price follows a normal distribution, and price options in a simple general equilibrium economy with a representative agent who has a generalized logarithmic utility function.  Compared to the Black-Scholes model, our square root option pricing model has two more parameters, but is still easy to implement.  The square root option pricing model produces significantly smaller fitting errors of option prices and generates a negatively sloped implied volatility function.