12. Consumer Theory Econ 494 Spring 2013.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
"Valuing Cultural Diversity in Cities: Challenges to Cultural Economics", Procida (Naples, Italy), 5th of September 200 Foundations of Microeconomic Theory.
Advertisements

UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Chapter 3 Preferences Choose the “best” thing one can “afford” Start with consumption bundles (a complete list of the goods that is involved in consumer’s.
Rational Consumer Choice. Chapter Outline The Opportunity Set or Budget Constraint Budget Shifts Due to Price or Income Changes Consumer Preferences The.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics
Indifference Curves and
UNIT I: Theory of the Consumer
How Consumers Make Choices under Income Constraints
Intermediate Microeconomics
Chapter Four Consumer Choice.
The Theory of Consumer Behavior The principle assumption upon which the theory of consumer behavior and demand is built is: a consumer attempts to allocate.
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
A Consumer Constrained Choice
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Axioms of Rational Choice
Theory of Consumer Behavior Basics of micro theory: how individuals choose what to consume when faced with limited income? Components of consumer demand.
1 Rational Consumer Choice APEC 3001 Summer 2007 Readings: Chapter 3 & Appendix in Frank.
CHAPTER 2 DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS: CONSUMER DEMAND Presenter’s name Presenter’s title dd Month yyyy.
Schedule of Classes September, 3 September, 10 September, 17 – in-class#1 September, 19 – in-class#2 September, 24 – in-class#3 (open books) September,
Preferences. Preference Relation The consumer strictly prefers bundle X to bundle Y: The consumer is indifferent between X and Y:
Consumer Behavior There are 3 steps involved in studying consumer behavior. Consumer preferences: describe how and why people prefer one good to another.
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Consumer Preferences and
1 13. Expenditure minimization Econ 494 Spring 2013.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Introduction to Economics
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Preferences. 2 Consumer Behavior Budget Set organizes information about possible choices available to a given consumer.
Indifference Curve Analysis
Chapter 3 A Consumer’s Constrained Choice
1 Indifference Curve and Consumer Choice. 2 Overview Illustrated using example of choices on movies and concerts Assumptions of preference –______________________.
11. Cost minimization Econ 494 Spring 2013.
Utility Maximization and Choice
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
Consumer behaviorslide 1 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Preferences. The conflict between opportunities and desires. Utility maximizing behavior.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
Consumer Theory Introduction Budget Set/line Study of Preferences Maximizing Utility.
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
Utility theory Utility is defined as want satisfying power of the commodity. Marginal Utility- Increase in the total utility as a result of consumption.
Consumer Choice, Utility, and Revealed Preference
Lecture 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 1 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2015 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Revealed.
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Econ 201 May 7, 2009 Indifference Curves Budget Lines and Demand Curves 1.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Question: Mary goes to the movies eight times a month and seldom goes to a bar. Tom goes to the movies once a month and goes.
Demand Analysis Some Questions What is behind a consumer’s demand curve? How do consumers choose from among various consumer “goods”? What determines.
Fundamentals of Microeconomics
Consumer Behavior & Utility Maximization ECO 2023 Chapter 7 Fall 2007 Created by: M. Mari.
Utility Maximization. Utility and Consumption ▫Concept of utility offers a way to study choices that are made in a more or less rational way. ▫Utility.
1 Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Each day involves decisions about how to allocate scarce money and resources. As we balance competing demands and desires, we make the choices that define.
Each day involves decisions about how to allocate scarce money and resources. As we balance competing demands and desires, we make the choices that define.
Consumer Choice Perloff Chapter 4 Introduction Demand curve –As price of a good increases we buy less of it. Consumers are making a choice What governs.
10. Envelope Theorem Econ 494 Spring Agenda Indirect profit function Envelope theorem for general unconstrained optimization problems Theorem Proof.
Rational Consumer Choice Chapter 3. Rational Choice Theory Assumption that consumers enter the market place with clear preferences Price takers Consumers.
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
Choice.
Choice.
Presentation transcript:

12. Consumer Theory Econ 494 Spring 2013

Agenda Shifting gears…Focus on the consumer, rather than the firm Axioms of rational choice Primal: Utility maximization  Marshallian demands Dual: Expenditure minimization  Hicksian demands Link between utility max and expenditure min. Welfare measures Readings Silb. Ch 10; also p 53-55

Introduction Consumers purchase goods, x1…xn, at prices, p1…pn. Consumers have a budget or income (M) with which to purchase these goods/services How do consumers decide what to buy? Buy goods to make them happy Derive satisfaction from consumption This satisfaction can be described by a utility function Consumers will maximize utility s.t. budget constraint

Axioms of rational choice These are behavioral postulates  no need to prove Budget constraint is straightforward, but notion of a utility function is not. We assert that consumer preferences must exhibit the following characteristics:

1. Completeness Individuals are always able to choose between two bundles Consumers can rank bundles Binary preference comparison One of the following must be true: A is preferred to B B is preferred to A A and B are equally preferred

2. Transitivity The rankings consumers assign to bundles must be consistent or transitive We only require that consumers can compare 2 bundles at a time, but the pairwise comparisons must be linked Transitivity: If A is preferred to B, And if B is preferred to C, Then A must be preferred to C.

Comment on transitivity Assuming transitivity is somewhat controversial There is some evidence that indicates that choices are not always transitive 3. Reflexivity Bundle A is at least as preferred as itself Almost obvious, requires only very weak logical behavior

The 1st 3 axioms The first 3 axioms: Completeness Transitivity Reflexivity These formalize the notion that the consumer’s choices are rational or logically consistent. These require that individuals can rank choices  ordinal measure of satisfaction/utility Does not require individuals to assign some level or degree of satisfaction with these choices  not cardinal measure  Utility function is only a ranking. If A is preferred to B, then U(A) > U(B)

Utility is an ordinal measure Ordinality  individuals can rank bundles If U(A)=50 and U(B)=25, then A is preferred to B, but we cannot say that A is preferred twice as much as B. Utility function is not unique – can take a monotonic transformation Any transformation that preserves rankings U0(x) = x2 or U1(x) = 2ln(x) will work just as well

4. Continuity & differentiability Mathematical assumptions about utility function Continuity If A is strictly preferred to B, then there is a bundle “close” to A that is also preferred to B Differentiability Utility function is twice differentiable

5. Non-satiation The utility function is monotonically increasing in the consumption of each good “More is preferred to less”

6. Substitution Consumers can make trade-offs among goods Assume bundles are perfectly divisible The maximum x2 a consumer will give up to get 1 unit of x1 is the amount that will leave her indifferent between old and new situation Indifference curves (analogous to isoquants) Slope of indifference curve represents trade-offs person is willing to make Indifference curve – locus of consumption bundles that yield same level of utility

Indifference curves slope down An explicit function for an indifference curve: Substitute into utility function to get identity: Differentiate identity wrt x1: Downward sloping indifference curves is implied by assumption of nonsatiation Indifference curves are mathematically the same idea as isoquants for production functions Rearrange terms:

Marginal rate of substitution A negatively sloped indifference curve means consumers are willing to make trade-offs  less of one good for more of the other Marginal rate of substitution (MRS)

Indifference curves are convex The marginal value of any good decreases as more of that good is consumed. Diminishing MRS  ¶2x1 / ¶x22 > 0 Differentiate MRS wrt 𝑥 1 See notes #8 slides 25-26 for derivation

Graphical illustration At point a, consumer is willing to give up more x2 for a unit of x1 than at point b.

Indifference curves cannot cross A and B are on same indifference curve U(A) = U(B) = U1 A and C are on same indifference curve U(A) = U(C) = U2 By transitivity, it must be true that U(B) = U(C) But…C includes more of both goods than B. By nonsatiation: U(B) < U(C) Contradiction  curves cannot cross

Indifference maps We can fully describe a utility function, and hence an individuals preferences in (x2, x1) space by an indifference map. U2 > U1

Utility maximization Suppose a consumer gets utility from 2 goods and has income M. The indirect utility function is: Assume person spends all her money. V (p1, p2, M) is quasi-convex in (p1, p2) we are not going to prove this

FONC – Slope of indifference curve – Slope of budget line

Tangency of indifference curve and budget line

SOSC Strict quasi-concavity of the utility function assures us that the indifference curves will be strictly convex We do NOT know sign of U11 and U22 !!  Diminishing marginal utility not implied

Marshallian demand functions By the IFT, if the SOSC are satisfied then the FONC can, in principle, be solved simultaneously for the explicit choice functions (Silb., p. 262, lays the IFT conditions out more formally): xim(p1, p2, M) i=1,2 lm(p1, p2, M) xim(p1, p2, M) are utility maximizing demands also referred to as Marshallian demand functions or money-income-held-constant demands

Elasticities

Marshallian demands are HOD(0) in prices and income For prices & income (p1, p2, M), the FONC: For prices & income (tp1, tp2, tM), the FONC: Since the FONC are the same for both sets of prices, the solutions must also be the same. Therefore, xim(p1, p2, M) = xim(tp1, tp2, tM)

Comment on homogeneity HOD(0) implies that “relative” price matter Consumption choices will not change with inflation if all prices and wages are increased at the same rate Consumption opportunities do not change if prices and income change by same proportion.

Marshallian demands are invariant to positive monotonic transformation The demand functions that solve: Are identical to the demand functions that solve: see Silb p. 53-55, 264-5 Read his discussion on why “diminishing marginal utility” has no meaning with ordinal utility.

Proof of invariance to monotonic transformation Since FONCs are identical, xim that solve FONCs must be identical. Note that U1/U2 = p1/p2 holds if F ' >0 or F ' <0. But if F ' <0, then an increase in both x1 and x2 would decrease utility. Hence, F ' <0 would correspond with minimizing utility. If F ' >0, then U and Û will move in same direction, and U will achieve a maximum IFF Û does. (See Silb p. 264 Proposition 1)

Comment on monotonic transformation This proposition highlights the ordinal nature of preferences. A positive monotonic transformation preserves the ranking of all bundles A positive monotonic transformation says nothing about the behavior of the individual

Envelope theorem The indirect objective function is: Apply envelope theorem:

Characteristics of indirect utility function Indirect utility function is: Non-increasing in prices Proof: ¶V / ¶pi < 0 from previous slide Non-decreasing in income Proof: ¶V / ¶M > 0 from previous slide Indirect utility function is HOD(0) in prices and income Proof: since Marshallian demands are HOD(0): Indirect utility fctn is quasi-convex in prices (p1, p2) We will not prove this… Why is indirect utility HOD(0), but indirect profit and indirect cost functions are HOD(1)?  Utility function does not have any parameters explicitly. All parameters are in the constraint.

Roy’s identity Solving for xi, and using lm = ¶V / ¶M : This relationship is known as Roy’s identity

Interpreting l See Silb., p. 266-7 At any given consumption point, additional utility, Ui, can be gained by consuming “a little more” xi. The marginal cost of this extra xi is pi.  The marginal utility per dollar spent on xi is Ui / pi

Use Envelope Theorem to Interpret l The Lagrange multiplier is always interpreted as the marginal effect on the optimal value of the objective function as the constraint changes. lm(p1, p2, M) is the marginal utility of income

Comparative statics Earlier, we used the IFT to solve the FONC: xim(p1, p2, M) i=1,2 lm(p1, p2, M) If we substitute these explicit choice functions back into the FONC, we get the following identities:

Comparative statics for p1 Differentiate the identities wrt p1, then express in matrix form:

Apply Cramer’s rule to solve Signs are indeterminate If M increases, cannot use less of both goods – would violate budget constraint Find ¶x2m / ¶p1 on your own Why is sign indeterminate? Parameters show up in the constraint.

Show: Cannot use less of both goods (when income increases) Substitute solution back into budget constraint: Differentiate wrt M:

Engel Aggregation Convert to elasticity form:

Cournot aggregation Note that if p1 increases, you could consume less of both goods.

Cournot and Engel Aggregation Cournot and Engel aggregation can be useful when estimating demand functions Can be used as a restriction in a regression Or, can test whether estimated coefficients are consistent with this.

Slutsky (later we will prove) Find the sign, using comp. static results: