Chapter 16 Equilibrium Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p): at any given price p, how many units.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Competition and the Market
Advertisements

Applications of supply and demand
Welfare Analysis Consumer Surplus; Producer Surplus
Chapter 8 Welfare Economics and The Gains From Trade
Chapter 5 Some Applications of Consumer Demand, and Welfare Analysis.
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
1 Equilibrium Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by sellers.  An equilibrium.
Demand, elasticities, market equilibrium, revenue, deadweight loss (Course Micro-economics) Ch Varian Teachers: Jongeneel/Van Mouche.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley CHAPTER 1. © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
CHAPTER 5 Efficiency.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Equilibrium. 2 Partial Equilibrium We have now derived both the market demand curve (Q d (p)) and market supply curve (Q.
CHAPTER 16 EQUILIBRIUM.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market clears or is in equilibrium when the total quantity demanded by buyers exactly equals the total.
Chapter 15 APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
Elasticity and Government Excise Tax Revenue Activity 21.
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
Chapter 6 Market Efficiency and Government Intervention.
Taxation, income distribution, and efficiency
Equilibrium and Efficiency
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Equilibrium Introduce supply Equilibrium The effect of taxes Who really “pays” a tax? The deadweight loss of a tax Pareto efficiency.
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
Chapter 15 Market Interventions McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Which curve is the demand curve? –Curve 1 Which curve is the marginal revenue curve? –Curve 2 Why? –For a monopoly to sell more, they must decrease price,
Consumer and Producer Surplus: Effects of Taxation
TAXES! Why do I tax all the time?. How Taxes Affect Market Outcomes Market not efficient – Total surplus not maximized When a good is taxed, the quantity.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Harcourt Brace & Company Chapter 7 Consumers, Producers and the Efficiency of Markets.
Welfare Economics Consumer and Producer Surplus. Consumer Surplus How much are you willing to pay for a pair of jeans? As an individual consumer, you.
Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus by Hal Varian Homework Midterm (50%) (11/10) Final (50%) (1/12) Mon 1:30-2:00 or by appointment.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
1 Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange Market Equilibrium and Efficiency Economic efficiency exists when no change could be made to benefit one party without.
1 Chapter 7 Consumer Choice and Elasticity. 2 Overview  Fundamentals of consumer choice and diminishing marginal utility  Consumer equilibrium  Income.
Unit 2 The Product Market 20 to 30%.
Consumption, Production, Welfare B: Competitive markets (partial eq) Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester 2013.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Firms in Perfectly Competitive Markets. A. Many buyers and sellers B. The goods are the same C. Buyers and sellers have a negligible impact on the market.
Discussion Session 4 - Review 07/15/2015. Supply and Demand through a Labor Lens In the labor market, demand comes from firms who “consume” labor to produce.
Unit II: The Nature and Function of Product Markets
Chapter 8 The Costs of Taxation Ratna K. Shrestha.
The Incidence of Taxation. The incidence of taxation Indirect taxes.
Chapter 15 Market Demand One can think of the market demand as the demand of some “ representative consumer ”.
Chapter 8 The Costs of Taxation. Objectives 1. Understand how taxes reduce consumer and producer surplus 2. Learn the causes and significance of the deadweight.
P Q 0 Excise Tax: Analysis of a $1/unit excise tax S D Pe Qe.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency. What Makes a Market Competitive? Buyers and sellers have absolutely no effect on price Three characteristics: Absence.
Excise Tax And Allocative Efficiency. Effect of a $.15 Excise Tax QuantitySupply Price Before Tax Supply Price After Tax.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 16 Equilibrium.
What happens to price and quantity for a firm when it is faced with a lump – sum tax/subsidy? Explain. Question 1.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 16 Equilibrium.
MICROECONOMICS Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity
Economics 2010 Lecture 9 Markets and efficiency. Competition and Efficiency  The Key Question  Allocative Efficiency  The Invisible Hand  Obstacles.
Effect of a tax on price and quantity S + tax S O P1P1 Q1Q1 D P Q.
CHAPTER 16 EQUILIBRIUM Supply Supply curve  It measures how much the firm is willing to supply of a good at each possible market price.  The supply.
We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets?
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 6-1 CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all.
The costs of taxation. Tax Usually taxes are collected because government wants to run the country. Some people believe that all taxation creates market.
16 Equilibrium.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium.
Chapter Six: Welfare Analysis.
CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p): at any given price p, how many units the suppliers are willing to supply. We have the market demand D(p) and the market supply S(p). Basically the market curve is the horizontal sum of the individual curves. Now we can determine the market equilibrium.

Solve D(p*)=S(p*). Then at p* (taking price as given), consumers choose the best they can afford (utility maximization) and this results the quantity demanded by all consumers D(p*). Similarly, at p* (taking price as given), producers choose the best they can produce (profit maximization) and this results the quantity supplied by all suppliers S(p*).

Furthermore, D(p*)=S(p*) implies that market clears. So we have an equilibrium.

The idea is, at the equilibrium price, consumers max utilities, producers max profits, and the market clears. The equilibrium price is determined by all, yet any individual is small so that when making a choice, he takes the price as given. When p S(p), some suppliers realize that they can sell at a higher price to satisfy disappointed consumers. This results a price increase pressure.

When p> p*, typically D(p)<S(p), some suppliers are unable to sell and they try to undercut the current price. This results a price decrease pressure. The comparative statics is to see how the equilibrium changes when the demand or the supply changes. Look at an example: a quantity tax on a good. A quantity tax is a tax levied per unit of quantity bought or sold.

As it suggests, either suppliers or consumers are supposed to pay the tax t. So whether the tax incidence (who gets to pay and how much) will be the same in the two cases? Consider the case where the supplier has to pay. Suppose at p, before the tax, suppliers supply x. After the tax, if the suppliers supply x, the price must be p+t since what matters is the price that the suppliers can put into their pockets.

Alternatively, suppose consumers have to pay the price. Suppose at p, before the tax, consumers consume x. After the tax, if consumers still consume x, the price must be p-t since what matters is the price that the consumers have to take out of their pockets. The two cases give you same results?

Fig. 16.3

Fig. 16.4

We can also talk about the tax incidence a bit. Imagine two extreme cases. One where the supply is perfectly inelastic, the other where it is perfectly elastic. Suppose before the tax the equilibrium price is p. In the former case, no way you can get consumers to take more than p out of pockets. So producers pay all the tax. In the latter case, no way you can make producers to take in less than p, so consumers pay all the tax.

Fig. 16.5

These two extreme cases suggest that the tax incidence has a lot to do with the elasticities of demand and supply. When it is more like the former, producers pay most of the tax. When it is more like the latter, consumers pay most of the tax.

Fig. 16.6

Can also talk about the welfare loss of a tax. A quantity tax t makes the marginal willingness to pay higher than the marginal willingness to supply by t. So for all units where MWP>MWS, there is a deadweight loss (should be produced, but are not produced).

Alternatively, can calculates the change of consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus to reach the same conclusion. So why on earth is the market equilibrium so efficient (Pareto efficient)? Think about what Pareto efficiency means. If MWP  MWS, it is not efficient because say if MWP>MWS, at least a consumer and a producer can strike a price inbetween to produce an additional unit and the consumer is better off while the producer is making more profit.

Fig. 16.7

It is clear that market equilibrium makes MWP=MWS. What about looking at consumers only? If MWP 1 >MWP 2 (say 5>4), then consumer 1 can buy a unit of good in concern from consumer 2 at the price of 4.5. This will make both 1 and 2 better off. Market equilibrium achieves MWP 1 =MWP 2 because MWP 1 =p=MWP 2.

Look at producers only, if MWS 1 >MWS 2 (say 5>4), then producer 2 can produce a unit of good in concern more and this increases 2’s cost by 4. Producer 1 can reduce its production by a unit and this decreases 1’s cost by 5. So in total, a cost of 1 dollar is saved and this saved cost (saved resource) can be used to produce. Market achieves MWS 1 =MWS 2 because MWS 1 =p=MWS 2.