The Measurement of Nonmarket Sector Outputs and Inputs Using Cost Weights 2008 World Congress on National Accounts and Economic Performance Measures for.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 6 Matrix Algebra.
Advertisements

1 Volume measures and Rebasing of National Accounts Training Workshop on System of National Accounts for ECO Member Countries October 2012, Tehran,
 Introduction  Simple Framework: The Margin Rule  Model with Product Differentiation, Variable Proportions and Bypass  Model with multiple inputs.
Random effects estimation RANDOM EFFECTS REGRESSIONS When the observed variables of interest are constant for each individual, a fixed effects regression.
Regression Analysis Using Excel. Econometrics Econometrics is simply the statistical analysis of economic phenomena Here, we just summarize some of the.
Algebra Problems… Solutions Algebra Problems… Solutions © 2007 Herbert I. Gross Set 4 By Herb I. Gross and Richard A. Medeiros next.
LINEAR REGRESSION MODEL
Chain-linking and rebasing of national accounts Expert Group Meeting on National Accounts Cairo May 12-14, 2009 Presentation points.
Chapter 5 Heteroskedasticity. What is in this Chapter? How do we detect this problem What are the consequences of this problem? What are the solutions?
Chapter 9 Simultaneous Equations Models. What is in this Chapter? In Chapter 4 we mentioned that one of the assumptions in the basic regression model.
The Reconciliation of Industry Productivity Measures with National Measures: An Exact Translog Approach EMG Workshop 2006 December 13, 2006 Erwin Diewert.
Algorithmic Problems in Algebraic Structures Undecidability Paul Bell Supervisor: Dr. Igor Potapov Department of Computer Science
Algebra Problems… Solutions Algebra Problems… Solutions © 2007 Herbert I. Gross Set 21 By Herbert I. Gross and Richard A. Medeiros next.
Definition and Properties of the Production Function Lecture II.
1 10. Joint Moments and Joint Characteristic Functions Following section 6, in this section we shall introduce various parameters to compactly represent.
1 Production APEC 3001 Summer 2007 Readings: Chapter 9 &Appendix in Frank.
CHAPTER 5 – Session 11 United Nations Statistics Division/DESA Revision of the Index of Industrial Production (IIP) publication by the UNSD.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Changes in the Terms of Trade and Canada’s Productivity Performance 2008 World Congress on National Accounts and Economic Performance Measures for Nations,
African Centre for Statistics United Nations Economic Commission for Africa Chapter 11: Chapter 11: Supply and use tables to input-output tables Ramesh.
Index Numbers. Fro measuring changes in a variable or a group of related variables with respect to time, geographical location, or other characteristics.
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
Production Chapter 9. Production Defined as any activity that creates present or future utility The chapter describes the production possibilities available.
Simpson Rule For Integration.
Rebasing and Linking of National Accounts
Measuring the Contributions of Productivity and the Terms of Trade to Australian Economic Welfare ABS and Productivity Commission Workshop on Productivity.
Nobel Prize - Economics Three Amigos Eugene Fama - U. Chicago Lars Peter Hansen - U. Chicago Robert Shiller - Yale Financial Economics American.
1 7. Two Random Variables In many experiments, the observations are expressible not as a single quantity, but as a family of quantities. For example to.
PRICE AND VOLUME MEASURES NATIONAL ACCOUNTS STATISTICS WORKSHOP PRICE AND VOLUME MEASURES Workshop on national accounts for Asian member countries of the.
Constant Price Estimates Expert Group Meeting on National Accounts Cairo May 12-14, 2009 Presentation points.
Efficiency Analysis of a Multisectoral Economic System Efficiency Analysis of a Multisectoral Economic System Mikulas Luptáčik University of Economics.
Managing input data Data requirements Managing non-response / missing data Quality adjustment.
Algebra Form and Function by McCallum Connally Hughes-Hallett et al. Copyright 2010 by John Wiley & Sons. All rights reserved. 3.1 Solving Equations Section.
Chapter 6 Index numbers. Index Numbers Index numbers allow relative comparisons over time It measures the percentage change in the value of some economic.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS AND GROWTH: THE GENERAL SOLOW MODEL Chapter 5 – second lecture Introducing Advanced Macroeconomics:
United Nations Economic Commission for Europe Statistical Division Producer Price Indices - Recommendations of international manuals Joint EFTA/UNECE/SSCU.
An Index Number Formula Problem: the Aggregation of Broadly Comparable Items Mick Silver International Monetary Fund Paper presented at the 2008 World.
Multiple Random Variables Two Discrete Random Variables –Joint pmf –Marginal pmf Two Continuous Random Variables –Joint Distribution (PDF) –Joint Density.
A.1The model is linear in parameters and correctly specified. PROPERTIES OF THE MULTIPLE REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS 1 Moving from the simple to the multiple.
 GDP 1990 = Output 1990  Prices 1990 = $5,546.1 billion  GDP 1994 = Output 1994  Prices 1994 = $6,736.9 billion This appears to be a very substantial.
Comparing Growth and Labour Productivity - measurement issues OECD Working Paper Presented by Francois Lequiller (OECD)
Uncertainty Management in Rule-based Expert Systems
Capitalization of R&D in the national accounts of Israel.
1 The Decomposition of a House Price index into Land and Structures Components: A Hedonic Regression Approach by W. Erwin Diewert, Jan de Haan and Rens.
 Definition  Unweighted and Weighted Index Numbers ( Simple Index Numbers, Laspeyre’s, Paasche’s Index, Fisher’s “Ideal” Index)  CPI ( Consumer Price.
AEG recommendations on COST OF CAPITAL SERVICES (Issue 15) Workshop on National Accounts December 2006, Cairo 1 UN STATISTICS DIVISION Economic Statistics.
Benson Sim UN STATISTICS DIVISION Demonstration on Rebasing and Linking of National Accounts Workshop on the Methodological Review of Benchmarking, Rebasing.
Sampling Design and Analysis MTH 494 Lecture-21 Ossam Chohan Assistant Professor CIIT Abbottabad.
1 HETEROSCEDASTICITY: WEIGHTED AND LOGARITHMIC REGRESSIONS This sequence presents two methods for dealing with the problem of heteroscedasticity. We will.
CS104:Discrete Structures Chapter 2: Proof Techniques.
1 REPARAMETERIZATION OF A MODEL AND t TEST OF A LINEAR RESTRICTION Linear restrictions can also be tested using a t test. This involves the reparameterization.
1 ICP PPP Methods Regional Course on Price Statistics and ICP Male, Maldives September 2005 TIMOTHY LO Statistician, International Comparison Program.
New Methodological Developments for the ICP W. Erwin Diewert Department of Economics University of British Columbia.
Getting Rental Prices Right for Computers by Erwin Diewert University of British Columbia and University of New South Wales and Hui Wei Australian Bureau.
Understanding Harmonic Limits per IEEE
Presented by: Dr Eman Morsi Decibel Conversion. The use of decibels is widespread throughout the electronics industry. Many electronic instruments are.
1 Chapter 4: Elements for a Conceptual Framework Workshop on Residential Property Price Indices: Statistics Netherlands, The Hague, February 10-11, 2011.
Comparison of Estimation Methods for Agricultural Productivity Yu Sheng ABARES the Superlative vs. the Quantity- based Index Approach August 2015.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 8 Matrices and Determinants.
Diewert Discussion of “Aggregate Productivity and the Productivity of the Aggregate: Connecting the Bottom- Up and Top-Down Approaches” by Bert M. Balk.
Index of Industrial Production: Methods of Compilation
Modeling approaches for the allocation of costs
Root-Locus Analysis (1)
7. Two Random Variables In many experiments, the observations are expressible not as a single quantity, but as a family of quantities. For example to record.
Price and Volume Measures
Competitive Industry Report and Calculations
7. Two Random Variables In many experiments, the observations are expressible not as a single quantity, but as a family of quantities. For example to record.
Rebasing and Linking of National Accounts
7. Two Random Variables In many experiments, the observations are expressible not as a single quantity, but as a family of quantities. For example to record.
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Presentation transcript:

The Measurement of Nonmarket Sector Outputs and Inputs Using Cost Weights 2008 World Congress on National Accounts and Economic Performance Measures for Nations, May by W. Erwin Diewert, Department of Economics, University of British Columbia

Introduction Can we obtain meaningful measures of Total Factor Productivity growth in the nonmarket sector, where real output growth is generally measured as real input growth? Answer: Yes, under two sets of conditions: (1)We can measure the output of an activity, the corresponding inputs and input prices or (2)We can measure a vector of outputs, the corresponding inputs and input prices and we are willing to undertake an econometric exercise. See the Appendix for an elaboration of this approach.

The simple cost based output prices model The model: (1)x i t = a i t y i t ; i = 1,2 (two activities) ; t = 0,1. x i t is a vector of inputs used by activity i in period t a i t is a vector of input output coefficients that describe the constant returns to scale, no substitution technology for activity i in period t; note that a i 0  a i 1. y i t is the (scalar) amount of output that is produced by the establishment in period t. Note that given x i t and y i t, we can determine a i t. We have no output price so we will use unit cost as the price of output in each period.

(2) C i t  w i t  x i t   n=1 N(i) w in t x in t ; i = 1,2 ; t = 0,1 C i t is the total cost in period t of producing y i t w i t is the vector of period t input prices The above framework allows for technical progress going from period 0 to 1; i.e., a i 0  a i 1. (3) w i 1  a i 1  w i 1  a i 0 ; i = 1,2; No technological regress (4) a i 0 = a i 1 ; i = 1,2; No technical change (5) w i 1  a i 1 < w i 1  a i 0 ; i = 1,2; Technical progress

Define the Laspeyres industry input quantity index Q L * as follows: (6) Q L *  [w 1 0  x w 2 0  x 2 1 ]/[w 1 0  x w 2 0  x 2 0 ] = [w 1 0  a 1 1 y w 2 0  a 2 1 y 2 1 ]/[w 1 0  a 1 0 y w 2 0  a 2 0 y 2 0 ] Similarly, the Paasche and Fisher industry input quantity indexes, Q P * and Q F *, can be defined as follows: (7) Q P *  [w 1 1  x w 2 1  x 2 1 ]/[w 1 1  x w 2 1  x 2 0 ] = [w 1 1  a 1 1 y w 2 1  a 2 1 y 2 1 ]/[w 1 1  a 1 0 y w 2 1  a 2 0 y 2 0 ] (8) Q F *  [Q L * Q P * ] 1/2.

Constructing industry input indexes is easy. But how are we to construct output indexes? The “best” approach would be to estimate user prices; i.e., how do users of the outputs value these nonmarket outputs? Unfortunately, such final demand prices are either not available or are not reproducible: so what to do? SNA 1993 recommends valuing publicly provided services at their costs of production. We follow this advice. (See also the Atkinson Review 2005). Thus in our present simple model, we set the price of each activity’s output, p i t, equal to average cost. In our more general Appendix model, we use econometrically estimated marginal costs.

(9) p i t  w i t  a i t ; i = 1,2 ; t = 0,1. Using the above cost based procedure i output prices p i t along with the corresponding period t output quantities y i t, we can readily define the Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher output quantity indexes, Q L, Q P and Q F respectively: (10) Q L  [p 1 0 y p 2 0 y 2 1 ]/[p 1 0 y p 2 0 y 2 0 ] = [w 1 0  a 1 0 y w 2 0  a 2 0 y 2 1 ]/[w 1 0  a 1 0 y w 2 0  a 2 0 y 2 0 ] (11) Q P  [p 1 1 y p 2 1 y 2 1 ]/[p 1 1 y p 2 1 y 2 0 ] = [w 1 1  a 1 1 y w 2 1  a 2 1 y 2 1 ]/[w 1 1  a 1 1 y w 2 1  a 2 1 y 2 0 ] (12) Q F  [Q L Q P ] 1/2.

Proposition 1: If there is no technical progress going from period 0 to 1 in each procedure, then the Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher output indexes are exactly equal to the corresponding Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher input indexes; i.e., we have: (13) Q L = Q L * ; (14) Q P = Q P * ; (15) Q F = Q F *. The above Proposition justifies current SNA practice, which frequently estimates nonmarket output growth by the corresponding input growth. But what if there is technical progress?

Proposition 2: If there is technical progress going from period 0 to 1 in either activity or procedure, then the Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher output indexes are strictly greater than the corresponding Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher input indexes; i.e., we have: (16) Q L > Q L * ; (17) Q P > Q P * ; (18) Q F > Q F *. Thus if there is technical progress in either procedure, then the above Proposition tells us that there will be Laspeyres, Paasche or Fisher productivity growth in the industry if we use the same index number formula (Laspeyres, Paasche or Fisher) for measuring both input and output growth.

The Introduction of a New More Efficient Technology The methodology developed in the previous section does not give reasonable results when, for example, a new medical technology is developed that is more efficient than an existing technology but the new technology does not immediately displace the old technology.

Procedure 1 is a well established “incumbent” procedure which has input-output coefficient vectors a 1 0 and a 1 1 in periods 0 and 1. Procedure 2 is a “new” improved procedure that accomplishes exactly what procedure 1 accomplishes but it is only available in period 1. The vector of input-output coefficients for procedure 2 in period 1 is a 2 1. We assume that one unit of the new procedure has a lower unit cost than one unit of the old procedure in period 1 so that (19) w 2 1  a 2 1 < w 1 1  a 1 1.

We assume that the incumbent technology does not suffer from technological regress; i.e., we assume that (3) w 1 1  a 1 1  w 1 1  a 1 0. We can use the period 1 input-output coefficients for the new technology as imputed input-output coefficients for period 0 but of course, the corresponding period 0 output and input for the new procedure, y 2 0 and x 2 0, should be set equal to zero; i.e., we make the following assumptions: (20) a 2 0  a 2 1 ; y 2 0  0 ; x 2 0  0.

We assume that the new procedure is also more efficient than the old procedure using the input prices of period 0; i.e., we assume that: (21) w 2 0  a 2 0 < w 1 0  a 1 0. We now get to the point of all this algebra. The “correct” output growth index should be the following unit value quantity index, Q UV : (22) Q UV  (y y 2 1 )/y 1 0. Thus output in period 1 is the sum of the two procedure outputs, y y 2 1, and this is divided by the procedure 1 output in period 0, y 1 0, to obtain the quantity output index.

But if we compute the Laspeyres output quantity index Q L defined by (10) under our current assumptions, we find that: (23) Q L  [p 1 0 y p 2 0 y 2 1 ]/[p 1 0 y p 2 0 y 2 0 ] = [w 1 0  a 1 0 y w 2 0  a 2 0 y 2 1 ]/[w 1 0  a 1 0 y w 2 0  a 2 0 y 2 0 ] = [w 1 0  a 1 0 y w 2 0  a 2 0 y 2 1 ]/w 1 0  a 1 0 y 1 0 using y 2 0 = 0 = [y 1 1 /y 1 0 ] + [w 2 0  a 2 0 /w 1 0  a 1 0 ][y 2 1 /y 1 0 ] < [y 1 1 /y 1 0 ] + [y 2 1 /y 1 0 ] = Q UV using definition (22). Thus treating the improved procedure as a totally new procedure that produces a different output and using the methodology in the previous section leads to a Laspeyres rate of growth that is below the “true” output growth, Q UV.

Similarly, if we compute the Paasche output quantity index Q P defined by (11) under our current assumptions, we find that: (24) Q P < Q UV and of course, (23) and (24) imply that (25) Q F < Q UV. Thus under the assumptions of this section, the methodology developed in the previous section will lead to estimates of output growth and productivity growth that are biased downwards.

The bias that results from the incorrect measurement of the effects of the introduction of a new and more efficient procedure is similar in many respects to new outlets bias; i.e., a new output is linked into an index in such a way that the index shows no change when in fact, a change should be recorded. The methodology for dealing with a new procedure developed above is relatively straightforward and is reproducible and objective under the assumptions of the model. However, in the real world, a new procedure is unlikely to have an output that is exactly equivalent to the output of an existing procedure and hence in real life, it will not be so straightforward to deal with new medical procedures.

Conclusion The valuation of outputs produced by the nonmarket sector is a complicated task. A first best solution would be to have unambiguous, objective and reproducible final demand prices but this solution is generally not available to statistical agencies. A second best solution is to value outputs at their average costs as is recommended in SNA We have developed the algebra associated with this second approach and found (not surprisingly) that it is possible to have Total Factor Productivity growth using this methodology, provided that sufficient information is available.