Pasternack1 Optimal Pricing and Return Policies for Perishable Commodities B. A. Pasternack Presenter: Gökhan METAN.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Vertical Relations and Restraints Many transactions take place between two firms, rather than between a firm and consumers Key differences in these types.
Advertisements

Objective 5.02 The Price Strategy.
Stochastic Inventory Modeling
HW #7 ANSWER
Understand Merchandise Planning in Retailing. The Merchandise Plan A budgeting tool that helps retailer or buyer to meet department goals ▫Planned sales.
Inventory Control Inventory: A stock of materials kept for future sale or use.
Supply Chain Contracts Gabriela Contreras Wendy O’Donnell April 8, 2005.
Principles of Marketing
Impact of Returns on Supply Chain Coordination Ana Muriel Department of Mechanical and Industrial Engineering, University of Massachusetts In collaboration.
1 Managing Flow Variability: Safety Inventory The Newsvendor ProblemArdavan Asef-Vaziri, Oct 2011 The Magnitude of Shortages (Out of Stock)
Chapter 5 Inventory Control Subject to Uncertain Demand
3 - 1 Cost-Volume-Profit Analysis Chapter Learning Objective 1 Understand the assumptions underlying cost-volume-profit (CVP) analysis.
1 Transfer pricing 6 maggio Horizontal dimension at the business unit level Business units as independent units which have the responsibility.
INDR 343 Problem Session
Supply Chain Coordination with Contracts
MNG221- Management Science –
Operations Management Session 25: Supply Chain Coordination.
1 Management Decision Making. 2 Lecture Outline Cost Volume Profit Analysis Equation Method Assessment of Risk Assumptions Contribution Margin Method.
Operations Management
Relevant Costs and Benefits
©2003 Prentice Hall Business Publishing, Cost Accounting 11/e, Horngren/Datar/Foster Cost-Volume-Profit Analysis Chapter 3.
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
Backup Agreements in Fashion Buying-The Value of Upstream Flexibility Eppen and Iyer (1997) Presented By: Hakan Umit 21 April 2003.
Supply Contracts and Risk Management David Simchi-Levi Professor of Engineering Systems Massachusetts Institute of Technology Tel:
Chapter 4 Solutions. Exercise 4-5A Since the product- and facility-sustaining costs do not differ between the alternatives, they are not avoidable. The.
5-1 ISE 315 – Production Planning, Design and Control Chapter 5 – Inventory Control Subject to Unknown Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2005 by The.
Marketing by the Numbers
1 INVENTORY MODELS Outline Deterministic models –The Economic Order Quantity (EOQ) model –Sensitivity analysis –A price-break Model Probabilistic Inventory.
PRICING CONCEPTS FOR ESTABLISHING VALUE
Inventory Inventory is the stock of goods, commodities or other economic resources that are stored for the smooth and efficient running of a business.
Inventory Management MD707 Operations Management Professor Joy Field.
Channel Coordination and Quantity Discounts Z. Kevin Weng Management Science, Volume 41, Issue 9 (September, 1995), Prepared by: Çağrı LATİFOĞLU.
Lesson 1: Pricing. Objectives You will:  Calculate price based on unit cost and desired profit  Compute margin based on price and unit cost  Maximize.
Pricing: Understanding and Capturing Customer Value
Contribution. Definition of contribution Contribution is the difference between sales revenue and variable cost Contribution is the difference between.
1 Managing Flow Variability: Safety Inventory Operations Management Session 23: Newsvendor Model.
Pricing Products: Understanding and Capturing Customer Value 10 Principles of Marketing.
WIN WIN SITUATIONS IN SUPPLY CHAIN MANAGEMENT Logistics Systems 2005 Spring Jaekyung Yang, Ph.D. Dept. of Industrial and Information Systems Eng. Chonbuk.
Short-Run Decision Making; Relevant Costing and Inventory Management Management Accounting: The Cornerstone for Business Decisions Copyright ©2006 by South-Western,
© 2007 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Marketing Management, 8e Chapter Eleven Pricing Strategy Key Words / Outline.
Channel Coordination and Quantity Discounts Z. Kevin Weng Presented by Jing Zhou.
1 INTRODUCTION TO MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING Lecture 3 & 4.
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd, Accounting for Managers, 1Ce, Ch 8 1.
Chapter 15 Retail Pricing McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Entrepreneurship CHAPTER 11 SECTION 1.  To stay in business, you must make a profit.  Costs and expenses can be fixed or variable: 1.Fixed costs – do.
© Thomson/South-Western ECONOMIC EDUCATION FOR CONSUMERS Slide 1 Consumer’s Role in the Economy Objectives: By the end of class, students will be able.
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the monopoly model (I): standard pricing ………….1optimal production ………….2 optimal.
Homework 1- Gateway.
The Process of Merchandise Planning
By: Imad Feneir.
Transfer Pricing Chapter 15
EMPLOY PRICING STRATEGIES TO DETERMINE OPTIMAL PRICING
microeconomics spring 2016 the analytics of
Historical Distribution
Pricing Considerations
Principles of Marketing
Pricing: Understanding and Capturing Customer Value
Determining Optimal Level of Product Availability
Chapter 8: Selecting an appropriate price level
Pricing Products and Services
Chapter 12 Determining the Optimal Level of Product Availability
Section 4.4 Applications to Marginality
Pricing Methods Cost-based pricing
Cost-Volume-Profit Analysis
ECONOMICS : CHAPTER 5-- SUPPLY
Chapter 9: Setting the list or quoted price
Supply Chain Contracts and their Impact on Profitability
Objective 5.02 The Price Strategy.
Price Strategy Considerations
Operations Management
Presentation transcript:

Pasternack1 Optimal Pricing and Return Policies for Perishable Commodities B. A. Pasternack Presenter: Gökhan METAN

Pasternack2 Outline i)Introduction ii) Model iii) Implications iv) Examples v) Conclusion

Pasternack3 Introduction Introduction What the paper is all about?  Pricing policies for a manufacturer that produceses goods with short shelf or demand life. Pricing Policy:Specifies the price of the commodity charged from the retailers, per unit credit for the returned goods, and the percentage of purchased goods allowed to be returned for this credit.

Pasternack4 Introduction Introduction Question: How would you set the price of the product for your retailers, and what return policy would you impose? How and what kind of decisions are made typically? Price: i- Cost basis decisions ii- “What market will bear” approach Return Policy: i- Full credit for all unsold goods. ii- No credit for unsold goods. No channel coordination!

Pasternack5 Introduction Introduction Set a pricing policy Purchase Decision Price, demand, product availability Customer Side Profit

Pasternack6 Introduction Introduction Assumptions about the model: iii- Any retailer place only one order from the manufacturer. i- Single item is considered. ii- Item has short shelf or demand life. iv- Goodwill cost is incurred partially by the retailer and partially by the manufacturer. (when inventory is depleated) v- Certain amount may be returned to the manufacturer for partial credit and the remaining is disposed of by the retailer for its salvage value. (when inventory remains beyond the shelf/demand life)

Pasternack7 Introduction Introduction Assumptions about the model:Cont’d vi- Manufacturing cost per item is independent of the production quantity. vii- All the retailers charge the same (fix) price for the product. viii- Both the manufacturer and the retailers are profit maximizers. ix- Salvage value is same for manufacturer and the retailers. x- No transfer mark-ups between retailers and the manufacturer. (amount paid by the retailer = amount received by the manufacturer)

Pasternack8 Introduction Introduction Assumptions about the model:Cont’d xi- Demand at the retail level is stochastic. xii- Manufacturer has control of the channel and is free to set the pricing policy. Retailers decide to carry the commodity or not. Objective: To develop a pricing policy that optimizes the expected profit of both the manufacturer and the retailers as well as to achieve the channel coordination.

Pasternack9 Introduction Introduction Methodology: Single period inventory model (newsboy problem) is employed in the analyses. Interest: Not finding the optimal ordering quantity! What pricing policy for the manufacturer will be optimal ?

Pasternack10 Model Model

Pasternack11 Model Model Unit selling price by the retailer Unit price paid by the retailer to the manufacturer. Salvage value per unit Manufacturing cost per item

Pasternack12 Model Model In the analyses we will consider two cases: 1) We will first assume such a system that the retailers belong to manufacturers own. That is, they are company stores. 2) In the second case, we will consider indedendent retailers. That is, the retailers determine their order quantity. This will enable us to determine the optimal policy for the system as a whole. This will enable us to determine the optimal policy for retailers where they are independent.

Pasternack13 Model Model 1 st CASE Let the company produces Q units and sells directly to the customers by its own retailers and EP T (Q) be the total expected profit. Total manufacturing cost Expected profit when demand is less than the production quantity. Total Profit Total Salvage Value for unsold goods Expected profit when demand is more than the production quantity. Total Profit Total goodwill cost for lost demands

Pasternack14 Model Model Result  F(Q T * )=(p+g 2 -c)/(p+g 2 -c 3 )

Pasternack15 Model Model 2 nd CASE Let the retailer orders Q units and EP R (Q) be the retailer’s expected profit. Retailer’s total ordering cost

Pasternack16 RQ ORDER DEMAND 0 Q (1-R)Q x Retailer’s revenue from items sold Credit obtained for unsold goods from the manufacturer Total amount obtained for unsold goods from their salvage value Model Model

Pasternack17 ORDER DEMAND 0 Q RQ (1-R)Q x Retailer’s revenue from items sold Credit obtained for unsold goods from the manufacturer Model Model

Pasternack18 ORDER DEMAND 0 Q RQ (1-R)Q x Retailer’s revenue from items sold Total goodwill cost of the retailer. Model Model

Pasternack19 Model Model 00 00 Note that: Q * is the order quantity of independent retailer which satisfies equation (7).

Pasternack20 Model Model Now, the retailer orders Q* units and EP M (Q*) be the manufacturer’s expected profit. Profit obtained by the sales of Q* units to the retailer

Pasternack21 RQ* ORDER DEMAND 0 Q* (1-R)Q* x Total Credit paid for returned unsold goods minus the total salvage value obtained from these items by the manufacturer Model Model

Pasternack22 ORDER DEMAND 0 Q* RQ* (1-R)Q* x Total Credit paid for returned unsold goods minus the total salvage value obtained from these items by the manufacturer Model Model

Pasternack23 ORDER DEMAND 0 Q* RQ* (1-R)Q* x Total goodwill cost of the manufacturer (because of lost demand) Model Model

Pasternack24 Model Model Now what we have on hand? From Case-1 Analysis: We know that the manufacturer wants to maximize the total channel profit and hence wants: Q T * such that it satisfies F(Q T *)=(p+g 2 -c)/(p+g 2 -c3) From Case-2 Analysis: We know that the independent retailer wants to maximize its own profit and hence wants: Q* such that it satisfies:

Pasternack25 Model Model Hence set: Q*=Q T * such that it satisfies F(Q*)=F(Q T *)=(p+g 2 -c)/(p+g 2 -c3)

Pasternack26 Model Model The manufacturer has the control over the parameters c 1 (cost of per unit order from the manufacturer), c 2 (credit per unit paid by the manufacturer to the retailer for returned goods) and R (percentage of the order quantity, Q, that can be returned to the manufacturer for a credit of c 2 per item). Results:  If the manufacturer sets these three parameters in such a way that the previous equation is satisfied, the independent retailer should order the same quantity from the manufacturer as would the manufacturer if operating a company store.  This results in maximum total profits to the retailer and manufacturer, and the channel is said to be coordinated. Observations:  As there is no unique solution to the previous equation, different values for these there decision variables result in different divisions of expected profit between the manufacturer and the retailer.  Therefore, the manufacturer’s pricing and return policy will function as a risk sharing agreement between manufacturer and retailer.

Pasternack27 Implications Implications Theorem 1.The policy of a manufacturer allowing unlimited returns for full credit is system suboptimal.

Pasternack28 Implications Implications Theorem 2.The policy of a manufacturer allowing no returns is system suboptimal. Theorems 1 & 2 imply that “unlimited returns for full credit” as well as “no returns” prevents channel coordination. Theorem 3.A policy which allows for unlimited returns (R=1) at partial credit (c 2 <c 1 ) will be system optimal for appropriately chosen values of c 1 and c 2.

Pasternack29 Implications Implications If c 1 and c 2 are so chosen and the manufacturer allows for unlimited returns, then the total expected profit for the retailer and manufacturer are as follows:

Pasternack30 Implications Implications If the demand for the commodity follows a normal distribution (x ~ N(μ, σ)) then the previous equations become: OBSERVATIONS: c1 chosen at its low end (c1 = c + ε)  Manufacturer makes NO PROFIT c1 chosen at its high end (c1 =p – ε)  Retailer makes NO PROFIT

Pasternack31 Implications Implications As c 2 ↑ c 1 also ↑

Pasternack32 Implications Implications The pricing should be set so that the average retail establishment captures at least some portion of the gain from channel coordination. If it can be demonstrated to the retailers that their profits will improve as a result of price changes, then they should be more willing to accept the new pricing plan. Increasing the retailers’ profits should result in additional distribution outlets being opened, resulting in an increase in overall demand. REASONREASON

Pasternack33 Implications Implications A drawback!!! Multi-retailer Environment  Manufacturer sets a single (uniform) pricing policy for all retailers  Impacts on retailer profitability will be different A policy that increases retailers’ total profit does not guarantee to increase all individual retailer’s profit. Some may faced with a decrease in their expected profit due to the channel coordinated pricing policy. An easy but not feasible solution: A different and retailer-specific pricing policy can be determined and set for each retailer and this achieves the manufacturer’s goal. In fact it is not defendable under the Robinson-Patman Act (which is an act about the competition and pricing actions in business environment).

Pasternack34 Implications Implications Another issue  Goodwill Costs  Hard to Quantify  Vary among different retailers  A uniform pricing policy for those retailer can not be set  Fortunately, analyses show that when R=0 the retailers’ order quantity is insensitive to small changes in goodwill cost. A pricing policy for a new product! Desirable enough $$$ Ensure reasonable rate of return $$$$$$

Pasternack35 Examples Examples Consider a product with: Net retail price of $8.00(p=8). Manufacturing cost of $3.00(c=3) Salvage value of $1.00(c 3 =1 ) Retailer goodwill cost is $3.00(g=3) Manufacturer goodwill cost is $2.00(g 1 =2) Total goodwill cost is $5.00(g 2 =g+g 1 =5) g=3, g 1 =2, g 2 =5, p=8, c=3, c 1 =4, c 3 =1, R=0 Suppose that manufacturer charges $4.00 (c 1 =4) per item from the retailer and not permit returns for unsold goods (R=0).

Pasternack36 g=3, g 1 =2, g 2 =5, p=8, c=3, c 1 =4, c 3 =1, R=0 Examples Examples Assume a retailer: Demand ~ N(200, 50) and the retailer is a profit maximizer. Q*=226EP R (Q*)=$626.25EP M (Q*)=$ (1) From Theorem-2, this cannot be optimal! Manufacturer decides to allow unlimited returns to achieve channel coordination. Set R=1.

Pasternack37 Examples Examples g=3, g 1 =2, g 2 =5, p=8, c=3, c 1 =4, c 3 =1, R=1 From F(Q T * )=(p+g 2 -c)/(p+g 2 -c 3 ) c 1 =$4.28c 2 =$2.936 Q*=249EP R (Q*)=$643.51EP M (Q*)=$ (2) If all the gain is given to the retailer c 1 =$4.37c 2 =$3.044 Q*=249EP R (Q*)=$626.86EP M (Q*)=$ (3) If all the gain is given to the manufacturer

Pasternack38 c 1 =$4.32c 2 =$2.984 EP R (Q*)=$636.11EP M (Q*)=$ (4) Both Manuf. & Retailer benefit from the strategy Examples Examples Now suppose this is the selected policy...

Pasternack39 Examples Examples Consider a second retailer: Demand ~ N(200, 10) and the retailer is a profit maximizer. Before channel coordination (c 1 =4, R=0) Q*=205EP R (Q*)=$765.25EP M (Q*)=$ (5) After channel coordination (c 1 =4.32, R=1, c 2 =2.984) Q*=210EP R (Q*)=$716.02EP M (Q*)=$ (6)

Pasternack40 Conclusion Conclusion It is possible for a manufacturer to set a pricing and return policy which will ensure channel coordination. For partial return case, the optimal values for the selling price to the retailer and the return credit offered on the item will both be functions of the individual retailer’s demand.  Since retailers have different demand distributions  fixed price/return policies which allow for partial returns cannot be optimal.

Pasternack41 Conclusion Conclusion Policy: Unlimited returns for partial credit  Optimal values for selling price to the retailer and credit offered to the retailer can be determined independent of the retailer’s demand distribution.  A range of optimal values for selling price and return credits exist.  Choosing different pairs result in different divisions of the profit. As a result of channel coordination some retailers may face with a decrease in their expected profits. Since any manufacturer normally have a number of retailers, it is clear that the policy with full returns for partial credits is the suitable one for short-lived commodities

Pasternack42 THE END