Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 3 McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Advertisements

Rational Consumer Choice. Chapter Outline The Opportunity Set or Budget Constraint Budget Shifts Due to Price or Income Changes Consumer Preferences The.
Utilities Indifference curves
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Indifference Curves and
UNIT I: Theory of the Consumer
Consumer Preferences chapter 4
Chapter Four Consumer Choice.
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
1 Stephen Chiu University of Hong Kong Utility Theory.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Consumers’ preferences
CHAPTER 3 Utility Theory.
Theory of Consumer Behavior Basics of micro theory: how individuals choose what to consume when faced with limited income? Components of consumer demand.
Utility.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
Schedule of Classes September, 3 September, 10 September, 17 – in-class#1 September, 19 – in-class#2 September, 24 – in-class#3 (open books) September,
Consumer Behavior There are 3 steps involved in studying consumer behavior. Consumer preferences: describe how and why people prefer one good to another.
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
CHAPTER 5 Consumer Choice Theory. CHAPTER 5 Consumer Choice Theory.
Consumer preferences and utility Modelling consumer preferences.
Introduction to Economics
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Indifference Curve Analysis
Chapter 3 A Consumer’s Constrained Choice
Theory of Consumer Behavior
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand Chapter 8.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
Consumer Theory Introduction Budget Set/line Study of Preferences Maximizing Utility.
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
Indifference Curve Approach Topic 3. Outline Concepts—definition/illustration Indifference map Slope of indifference Curve/MRTS DMRTS/reasons Assumptions.
Theoretical Tools of Public Economics Math Review.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2015 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Revealed.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
Econ 201 May 7, 2009 Indifference Curves Budget Lines and Demand Curves 1.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Chapter 3 Consumer Preferences.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Question: Mary goes to the movies eight times a month and seldom goes to a bar. Tom goes to the movies once a month and goes.
SARBJEET KAUR Lecturer in Economics Indifference Curve Analysis.
Fundamentals of Microeconomics
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
CDAE Class 4 Sept. 6 Last class: 1.Introduction 2.Preferences and choice Class exercise 1 Today: 2. Preferences and choice Next class: 2.Preferences.
Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Consumer Behavior 3 C H A P T E R Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics.
CHAPTER 2 UTILITY AND CHOICE. Objective Build a model to understand how a consumer makes decisions under scarcity. To understand his choice we need to.
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Lecture 10slide 1 A primer on Consumer Choice Preferences, Indifference Curves and Utility.
The Consumer’s Optimization Problem
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
PPA 723: Managerial Economics
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility.
Preferences and Utility
C H A P T E R 3 Consumer Behavior CHAPTER OUTLINE
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Theory of Consumer Behavior
C H A P T E R 3 Consumer Behavior CHAPTER OUTLINE
Chapter 5.
Consumer Choice Indifference Curve Theory
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Subject:Economics Class:1st Semester
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility

Outline Introduction Description of consumer preferences The Utility functions Marginal utility and diminishing marginal utility Indifference curves Marginal rate of substitution Special functional forms

Introduction Supply and Demand Models (Ch. 2) are useful for analyzing economic questions concerning markets. How will increasing the real wage affect output? In these models we summed each individuals demand to obtain the market demand curve. But, how do individuals decide what to consume and how much to consume.

Introduction We need to develop a model about individual or consumer behavior Model is based on: Individual tastes or preferences determine the amount of pleasure people derive from goods and services. (Chapter 3) Consumers face constraints (budget) that limit their choices Consumers maximize their well-being or pleasure from consumption, subject to the constraints they face. We want our model to be realistic so we can predict consumer behavior. But, still as simple as possible.

Description of Consumer Preferences Consumer Preferences tell us how the consumer would rank any two basket of goods, assuming these allotments were available to the consumer at no cost. baskets or bundles is a collection of goods or services that an individual might consume.

Properties of Consumer Preferences The Assumptions of Consumer Behavior 1. Complete: Preferences are complete if the consumer can rank any two baskets of goods A strictly preferred to B (A  B ) B strictly preferred to A (B  A ) indifferent between A and B (A ≈ B)   Preferences are transitive if a consumer who prefers basket A to basket B, and basket B to basket C also prefers basket A to basket C 2. Transitive: No illogical behavior A  B and B  C → A  C NOT C  A

Properties of Consumer Preferences Monotonic (more is better) Preferences: are monotonic if a basket with more of at least one good and no less of any good is preferred to the original basket. – free disposal can’t be worse of with more The more is better assumption is also known as the property of non-satiation. It assumes are looking at what economists call a ‘good’. Something we want more of We are not looking at a ‘bad’ i.e. pollution We can relax this assumption it is the first two that are crucial for the analysis

Preferences Examples Which bundles are better because more is better?

Intransitivity and Age Number of Subjects Intransitive Choices (%) 4 39 83 5 33 82 6 23 7 35 78 8 40 68 9 52 57 10 45 11 65 37 12 81 13 41 Adults 99 Source: See Hirshleifer, Jack and D. Hirshleifer, Price Theory and Applications. Sixth Edition. Prentice Hall: Upper Saddle River, New Jersey. 1998.

Ordinal vs Cardinal Rankings Ordinal Ranking: gives us information on how a consumer ranks different baskets of goods. But it does not say by how much (i.e. 2 times as much) This is how we view preferences. Cardinal Rankings: Give us information on the intensity of the consumer preferences (i.e. they like basket A 10 times more than basket B). Would be hard to say I like eating pizza out 10.5 times more than eating bad Chinese. Putting an exact number to our preferences is hard! – this is why we use ordinal rankings for consumer preferences

Ordinal vs Cardinal Example Students take an exam. After the exam, the students are ranked according to their performance. An ordinal ranking lists the students in order of their performance (i.e., Harry did best, Joe did second best, Betty did third best, and so on). A cardinal ranking gives the grade of the exam, based on an absolute grading standard (i.e., Harry got 50, Joe got 100, so Joe did 2 times better than Harry).

Utility Function Utility Function: measures the level of satisfaction that a consumer receives from any basket of goods. U=F(x1,x2,x3, ….., xn), where the x’s are quantities of n goods that might be consumed in a period Is utility ordinal or cardinal? Utility is an ordinal concept: the precise magnitude of the number that the function assigns has no significance.

Utility Functions Difference in magnitudes of utility have no interpretation per se utility not comparable across individuals any transformation of a utility function that preserves the original ranking of bundles is an equally good representation of preferences.

Utility Function (one good in utility) Are the assumptions on preferences meet? U(y): total utility of muffins U(y) = y.5 1.75 C 1.5 B 1.0 A 1 2 3 y, weekly consumption of muffins Slopes on A and C give marginal utility – each additional unit makes person happy but by less than the previous unit

Marginal Utility Marginal Utility: Rate at which total utility changes as the level of consumption rises. Each new muffin makes you happier, but makes you happier by smaller and smaller amount.

Marginal Utility (more than one good) The marginal utility: of a good, x, is the additional utility that the consumer gets from consuming a little more of x when the consumption of all the other goods in the consumer’s basket remain constant. U/x (y held constant) = MUx=∂ U/∂ x U/y (x held constant) = MUy =∂ U/∂ y …or…the marginal utility of x is the slope of the utility function with respect to x.  The principle of diminishing marginal utility: states that the marginal utility falls as the consumer consumes more of a good

Marginal Utility MU(y): marginal utility of muffins 1.00 .50 .25 1 2 3 -If more is always better: marginal utility must always be positive. -Diminishing marginal utility -A positive marginal utility means you like the good. Otherwise you would get zero or perhaps negative marginal utility 1.00 .50 .25 1 2 3 y, weekly consumption of muffins

Utility Function and Indifference Curve (2 good example)

Indifference Curve (IC) Clothing 2 good graph (keeps it simple) - Along curve consumer is indifferent between each of the bundles of food and clothing Same level of utility for bundle A, B, and C A B C IC1 for U=4 food

Indifference Map: Clothing Are indifferent to any bundle along an indifference curve. But more is better so are better off as we move away from the origin. Preference direction ( happier the further away from the origin) IC2 for U = 6 IC1 for U=4 Food

Indifference Curves and Map An Indifference Curve or Indifference Set: is the set of all baskets for which the consumer is indifferent An Indifference Map: illustrates a set of indifference curves for a consumer, it is an ordinal ranking.  

Properties of Indifference Maps Monotonicity => indifference curves have negative slope …and… indifference curves are not “thick” Transitivity => indifference curves do not cross Completeness => each basket lies on only one indifference curve one more assumption usually is made: Averages preferred to extremes => indifference curves are bowed toward the origin (convex to the origin).

Monotonicity Case: consumers like both goods Clothing To meet monotonicity: preference curve must be in the these areas - downward sloping Preferred to A • A Less preferred IC1 Food

Monotonicity Clothing If more is preferred to less, IC cannot be thick. B would be preferred to A, so could not be on same CI curve. B A IC1 for U=4 food

Indifference Curves Cannot Cross clothing Suppose that B preferred to A. but..by definition of IC, B indifferent to C A indifferent to C => B indifferent to A by transitivity. Contradiction, B should be preferred to A due to monotonicity. IC2 IC1 • B • A C • food

Averages Preferred to Extremes Clothing A • (.5A, .5B) • IC2 • IC1 B Food

Example: For the indifference curves graphed below, are the underlying preferences: Complete? Transitive? Monotonic? IC1 IC2 IC3 IC4 y Preference direction x

Example: For the indifference curves graphed below, are the underlying preferences: Complete? Yes Transitive? Yes Monotonic? No IC1 IC2 IC3 IC4 y Want as much X as possible but don’t care about Y: So same X and more Y are not better off, so not monotonic. B Preference direction A x

Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution: A consumer’s willingness to substitute one good for another while maintaining the same level of satisfaction (i.e. slope of indifference curve remains the same). The marginal rate of substitution of x for y (MRSx,y) is the rate at while the consumer is willing to give up y in order to get more of x, holding utility constant. This assumes y is on the vertical axis and x the horizontal.

Marginal Rate of Substitution Graphically – slope of IC If you like both goods then both goods will have positive marginal utilities Then indifference curve must be negatively sloped, because if you give up one good need more of the other.

Marginal Rate of Substitution Mathematically Memorize/ derive

Marginal Rate of Substitution Examples At A, slope = -5 so willing to give up 5 y, for one more X MRS is 5 At B, slope = -2 so so willing to give up 2 y, for one more X MRS=2

Diminishing Rate of Marginal Substitution As move along x, MRS gets smaller (diminishes) For most good MRS is diminishing Curve is flatter Willing to give up less and less y for the same amount of x From A (MRS = 5) to point B (MRS = 2) IC are convex to origin Averages preferred to extremes

An indifference curve exhibits a diminishing rate of substitution: if the more of good x you have, the more you are willing to give up to get a little of good y…or…   The indifference curves get flatter as we move out along the horizontal axis and steeper as we move up along the vertical axis.

What type of goods are these? Perfect substitutes   Example: For the following indifference curves, what is the marginal rate of substitution between x and y is: 1, .5, 2, or 5? Is the MRS diminishing? y What type of goods are these? Perfect substitutes Does the MRS need to be 1 for each of these? No could be in a ratio of 2 to 1 (2 Oreo cookies for each glass of milk 3 2 1 IC1 IC2 IC3 x 1 2 3

Graphing an Indifference Curve y Example: Suppose U = xy, graph the utility curve if utility is equal to 10. 5 2 10 = xy 2 5 x

y Example: U=20 5 Preference direction 20 = xy 2 10 = xy 2 5 x