Normalerweise wird bei der grafischen Darstellung des neoklassischen Modells der “Kapitalmarkt” (das reale Kreditangebot der Haushalte und die reale Kreditnachfrage.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
The IS-LM Model: Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis
Advertisements

Lecture 2 The Microfoundations of Money - Part 1.
L11200 Introduction to Macroeconomics 2009/10
is inversely correlated with is more volatile than
Intermediate Macroeconomics
The Central Bank and the money market equilibrium
Chapter 36 - Lipsey. FINANCIAL ASSETS WealthBonds Interest earning assets Claims on real capital Money Medium of exchange.
Equilibrium in the goods and money markets Understanding public policy
Ch. 16: Output and the Exchange Rate in the Short Run.
Investment and Saving Decisions
Understanding the Concept of Present Value
Macroeconomics Chapter 111 Inflation, Money Growth, and Interest Rates C h a p t e r 1 1.
A closed economy, market-clearing model
Demand for goods & services
FIN 40500: International Finance Nominal Rigidities and Exchange Rate Volatility.
The basic macro model In this lecture, we will cover the fundamental macro model (also known as the IS-LM model). Developed in the 1950s/60s, economists.
Abel, Bernanke and Croushore (chapters 9.4, 9.5 and 9.6)
Chapter 17: Macroeconomics in an Open Economy © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. 1 of 32.
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada
The Theory of Aggregate Demand Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the role of money in the classical model. Learn the relationship between.
Aggregate Demand and the Classical Theory of the Price Level Chapter 5.
Chapter 17 Unemployment, Inflation, and Growth. 2 Introduction In Chapter 4, 5, 6, we have studied a classical model of the complete economy, but said.
The Asset Market, Money, and Prices
Macro Policy Debates neoclassical monetarists, Keynesians, and supply-side economics.
16:Investment, Capital, and Interest  Overview  How are business investment decisions made?  How are household saving decisions made?  How do investment,
Walras' Law and the Problem of Money Price Determinacy Rainer Maurer Paper presented at the Annual London Conference on “Money, Economy and Management”
MOHAMMAD IMRAN DEPARTMENT OF APPLIED SCIENCES JAHANGIRABAD EDUCATIONAL GROUP OF INSTITUTES.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Chapter 4. 2 The Theory of Production Representative Agent Economy: all output is produced from labor and capital and in.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the determinants of output. Understand how output is distributed. Learn.
Source: Mankiw (2000) Macroeconomics, Chapter 3 p Determinants of Demand for Goods and Services Examine: how the output from production is used.
V PART The Core of Macroeconomic Theory.
Exchange Rate Volatility and Keynesian Economics.
Macroeconomics Prof. Juan Gabriel Rodríguez
The demand for money How much of their wealth will people choose to hold in the form of money as opposed to other assets, such as stocks or bonds? The.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Chapter 5 Rate of Return Analysis: Single Alternative 5-1.
The economy at Full Employment Lecture notes 4 Instructor: MELTEM INCE.
The Balance of Payments: Linking the United States to the International Economy Current account records a country’s net exports, net income on investments,
AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT
Putting it all Together IS-LM-FE. The Macroeconomy.
1 of 33 © 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. CHAPTER OUTLINE 8 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants.
BlCh31 The Goods Market Some definitions (or identities): –Value of final production  –Total output  total output If aggregate sales is the same as aggregate.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 3 National Income Outline of model A closed economy, market-clearing model Supply side  factor markets (supply, demand, price)  determination.
Review of the previous lecture 1. Total output is determined by  how much capital and labor the economy has  the level of technology 2. Competitive firms.
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
1 Aggregate Expenditure and Aggregate Demand CHAPTER 25 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
XVII. New Keynesian Economics. XVII.1 AD – AS model once again Agregate demand : both in long and short term decreasing function of price Agregate supply.
Chapter 4 Money, Interest, and Income. The goods market and the IS curve Goods market equilibrium: Investment and the interest rate:  Relaxing the assumption.
Chapter 7 Aggregate demand and supply: an introduction.
Answers to Review Questions  1.Explain the difference between aggregate demand and the aggregate quantity demanded of real output. Ceteris paribus, how.
Financial Markets Chapter 4. © 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved The Demand for Money Suppose the financial markets include only.
Answers to Review Questions  1.What is a real money balance? If the nominal money supply increases 20 percent while prices increase 20 percent, what happens.
Presented By: Prof. Dr. Serhan Çiftçioğlu
Lecture 8: Markets, Prices, Supply and Demand I L11200 Introduction to Macroeconomics 2009/10 Reading: Barro Ch.6 11 February 2010.
The Modern Approach to Aggregate Demand The Demand for Money and the LM Curve.
Of 261 Chapter 28 Money, Interest Rates, and Economic Activity.
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw National Income: Where It Comes From.
Ricardian Equivalence Robert J. Barro, “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?” Journal of Political Economy (1974), Graduate Macroeconomics I ECON.
AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION Chapter 25 1.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 9-1 Chapter Outline The FE Line: Equilibrium in the Labor Market The IS Curve: Equilibrium in the Goods.
The Modern Approach to Aggregate Demand The Capital Market and the IS Curve.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Money and Banking Lecture 14.
LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMICS ECO306 FALL 2011 GHASSAN DIBEH.
Money Demand KEYNES’ LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE THEORY.
Lecture outline Crowding out effect Closed and open economies Ricardian equivalence revisited Debt burden and dead weight loss.
Public debt, Finite Horizons in NGM
Lecture 18 Towards general equilibrium
Chapter 11- Part 2 The Economy in the Short-run
4-1 The Demand for Money Money, which you can use for transactions, pays no interest. There are two types of money: currency, coins and bills, and checkable.
National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes
Presentation transcript:

Normalerweise wird bei der grafischen Darstellung des neoklassischen Modells der “Kapitalmarkt” (das reale Kreditangebot der Haushalte und die reale Kreditnachfrage der Unternehmen und des Staates) mit Hilfe von “Walras-Law” eliminiert. Dann wird das Modell mit einer Gleichung für den „Geldmarkt“ ergänzt („Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach“). Diese Vorgehensweise wurde schon vor einiger Zeit von Patinkin (1948) kritisiert (s.S. 8). Sie funktioniert hier, auch unter Missachtung dieser Kritik nicht, weil im Fall einer säkularen Stagnation auf dem „Kapitalmarkt“ und auf dem Gütermarkt ein Ungleichgewicht herrscht. Wie im folgenden gezeigt, kann – wie in Abbildung 2 geschehen – in dem Fall, dass Geld von der Notenbank und den Geschäftsbanken als Kredit angeboten wird („inside money“) das Geldangebot als eine Komponente des Kreditangebotes und die Geldnachfrage als eine Komponente der Kreditnachfrage modelliert werden:

Walras' Law and the Money Price Determinacy

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -3- Overview 1. The Problem of Walras 2. The Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach & Patinkin’s Criticism 3. Patinkin’s Solution: A Real Wealth Effect 4. Weil’s Criticism: Money Is Not Net Wealth in Ricardian Economies 5. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply 6.1. Example: A Textbook Macromodel 6.2. Example: The Case with N Goods 6. Conclusions 7. Appendix: The Inconsistency of the Neoclassical Dichotomy 8. Literature Detailed Paper “Walras' Law and the Problem of Money Price Determinacy“ available at:

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer The Problem of Walras ■Since Walras (1874) has shown that the validity of the budget constraints implies an equilibrium on the n th market, if n-1 markets are in equilibrium, there is one equation missing to unambiguously determine the money prices of goods. ■Some researchers have therefore given up the idea that money prices are well determined: ● In his book “Interest and Prices” Woodford (2003, p. 34) cites Wicksell (1898, pp ), “who compares relative prices to a pendulum that always returns to the same equilibrium position when perturbed, while the money prices of goods in general are compared to a cylinder resting on a horizontal plane, which can remain equally well in any location on the plane to which it may happen to be moved”. ■Contrary to this view, I show in the following: If money supply is modelled in an institutionally correct way, there will always be “an equation left” to allow for money price determinacy: Hence money prices too have the properties of a pendulum.

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer The Problem of Walras ■In an economy with N goods markets, only N-1 prices can be determined: ● Household budget with N goods: ● Adding up the budgets of all H households: ■Rearranging the sums: ≡ Lange (1942, p.50): “Walras’ Law”

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer The Problem of Walras ● Therefore, if N-1 markets are in equilibrium: ● The N th market too must be in equilibrium, as a subtraction of (2) from (1) shows: ≡ Patinkin (1965, p.35) : “Walras’ Law”

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer The Problem of Walras ■Consequently, if all households keep their budgets, only N-1 independent equations exist. => Even if the “counting criterion” holds, => it is only possible to determine N-1 relative prices in terms of the numéraire. The price of the numéraire is set equal to 1. ■Solution following the “Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach”: ● To determine the N money prices of all goods we can simply “add a money market equation” to determine the money price of the numéraire: N-1 relative prices determined by the N-1 independent market equilibrium conditions “Money price” of the numéraire “If the equation system is linear and the coefficient matrix of the linear equations is non-singular, the equality of the number of equations and the number of unknowns is sufficient for the existence of a unique solution.”

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -8- ■Patinkin’s criticism of the “Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach”: ● It leads to a logical contradiction: ♦ If there is a general market equilibrium on all N markets plus the money market, ♦ a duplication λ = 2 of all money prices will leave the N goods markets in equilibrium, since it does not change the relative prices: ♦ The money market equation however will display excess demand: ♦ However, by Walras’ Law this is not possible, since the money market must be in equilibrium, if all other markets are in equilibrium. ♦ Therefore, following Patinkin, the Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach leads to a logical contradiction! 2. The Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach & Patinkin’s Criticism

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Patinkin’s Solution: A Real Wealth Effect ■Patinkin’s solution: The Real-Balance-Effect ● Patinkin (1949) proposed the introduction of a wealth-effect by adding the real value of money holdings as a positively valued argument in the demand functions for goods: ● such that an increase of the price level leads to a decrease of the real value of money wealth and hence the emergence of excess supply of goods, ● which by Walras’ Law is consistent with excess demand for money:

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Weil’s Criticism: Money Is No Net Wealth ■Weil (1991) criticism: Money is no net wealth! ● Following Barro’s “Ricardian Equivalence” Weil shows that in a standard Ricardian (infinitely-lived representative agent) economy, even outside money holdings cannot be net wealth. ● The basic argument for the simplified case of a constant interest rate i = i t and an infinite time horizon, t = 1,2,.. ∞: Present value of the opportunity costs of holding money Value of money holdings

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Weil’s Criticism: Money Is No Net Wealth ■Weil (1991) criticism: Money is no net wealth! ■Mathematically equivalent alternative statement of the argument: ● Barro’s (1974) proof that government bonds are no net wealth under such circumstances: If the government increases its consumption and finances this by issuing government bonds, the representative household receives, on one hand, additional interest payments from these bonds plus the face value at the end of maturity. On the other hand, the present value of these payments equals exactly the additional future taxes, which the household has to pay to finance these interest payments plus redemption. Consequently the net present value of holding these bonds is zero for the household. ● Analogously, if the government increases its consumption and finances this by paying with banknotes, the representative household does, on one hand, not have to pay additional future taxes to finance any interest payments or the redemption, but receives, on the other hand, no interest payments and no repayment of the face value from holding these banknotes. Consequently the net present value of holding these banknotes in a Ricardian economy is for the same reasons zero as the net present value of holding government bonds. If instead of government consumption lump sum transfers to households are assumed, the argument does not change. The only difference in this case is that the disposable income of households stays constant at the end of the day, while in the case of government consumption, the disposable income is reduced.

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel ■The following calculations show based on the standard three market textbook macromodel that ● if money supply and demand is modeled ● in a realistic, institutionally correct way, there is always an equation left, which can be used to determine the money prices of goods – even in an Ricardian economy, where money is no net wealth.

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Markets: Household Budget: Government Budget: Firm Budget Household Budget: Government Budget: Firm Budget

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: There will not necessarily be an equi- librium on the goods market:

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -15- The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: There will not necessarily be an equi- librium on the goods market: 6. Alternative Solution: Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel There will not necessarily be an equi- librium on the goods market:

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -16- The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: 5.1. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -17- The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: 5.1. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -18- The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: 5.1. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -19- The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: 5.1. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel Only if money demand equals money supply, the goods market is in equilibrium!

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -20- The Three Market Neoclassical Macromodel The Outside Money CaseThe Inside Money Case Given the budgets constraints and an equi- librium on the labor and capital market: Consequently, to make sure that the goods market is in equilibrium, it is necessary to assume that the budget constraints hold, the labor and capital market are in equilibrium and that money demand is equal to money supply! 5.1. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel ■If money supply is larger than money demand, there will be excess demand for goods, which will cause the price level for goods to increase: ■If real money demand depends (as usual) on the real transaction volume divided by the money velocity, this increase of the price level will cause real demand supply to decrease so that the excess supply of money and – simultaneously – the excess demand for goods disappears: <= =>

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel Digression: Consequently, if money supply is institutionally correctly modelled, the above three market macromodel can be easily transformed into the standard textbook form: If the assumption is made that the budget constraints hold, three market equilibrium conditions are sufficient to guarantee a general market equilibrium: Either Labor market equilibrium: Capital market equilibrium: Money market equilibrium: Or Labor market equilibrium: Goods market equilibrium: Money market equilibrium: Consequently, the standard textbook system of market equilibrium conditions is compatible with the above described “outside money” case, as well as with the “inside money” case. The standard textbook model has in fact two monetary interpretations. The same holds of course for the Keynesian fixed price version of this model. => Goods market equilibrium Capital market equilibrium

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: A Textbook Macromodel ■As this text book macromodel shows, if money supply differs from money demand, a “transaction volume effect” will cause the price level to adjust and restore an equilibrium on the goods market. ■Consequently it is a “transaction volume effect” the determines the price level – there is no need for Patinkin’s “wealth effect” (or “real balance effect” or “Pigou effect”). ■The following calculations show that the same holds of course for the case of an economy with N goods and H households:

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: The Case with N Goods ■Starting point: An economy with H households, N goods markets and money supplied by the government: ● Household budget with N goods plus money demand: ● Government budget with N goods plus money supply: ● Adding up the budgets of all H households and the government:

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: The Case with N Goods ■If N-1 markets for goods are in equilibrium: ● The N th market will not necessarily be in equilibrium, as subtracting of (4) from (3) shows: ● Consequently, to make sure that the Nth goods market is in equilibrium, it is necessary to assume that the budget constraints hold, the N-1 markets are in equilibrium and that money demand is equal to money supply!

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -26- ■If money supply is larger than money demand, there will, as equation (3) shows, generally be excess demand for goods: ■Following the standard assumption, nominal money demand of a household depends on the nominal transaction volume of the household: 5.2. Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: The Case with N Goods

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer -27- ■Under this assumption, an increase of the price level will cause money demand to grow so that the excess supply of money and – simultaneously – the excess demand for goods disappears: ■As this model with N goods and H Households shows, if money supply differs from money demand, it is again a “transaction volume effect”, which will cause the price level to adjust and restore an equilibrium on the goods market. ■Consequently here too, it is a “transaction volume effect” the determines the price level – there is no need for Patinkin’s “wealth effect” Institutionally Correct Modelling of Money Supply: The Case with N Goods <= =>

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Conclusions 1.If money supply and money demand is modelled based on a realistic institutional setup in the budget constraints and market equations, the resulting number of independent equations is always equal to the number of goods. ● Consequently, if the “counting criterion” holds, there are always enough equations to determine the money prices of all goods in an economy. 2.If money demand depends on the transaction volume of the economy, it will be a “transaction volume effect”, which restores the monetary equilibrium but not a “wealth effect”. In so far, Patinkin (1948) is wrong and the Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach is right.

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Conclusions 3.However, Patinkin (1948) is right and the Neoclassical Dichotomy Approach is wrong in another important point: ● Money price determinacy excludes the assumption of “zero degree homogeneity” in money prices of supply and demand functions: A realistic institutional setup of money supply and money demand excludes the assumption of “zero degree homogeneity”. As the following appendix shows, if money supply and demand are modelled in an institutionally correct way, the assumption of “zero degree homogeneity” in money prices, leads to a logical contradiction. 4.As a result of this all: The standard procedure used in many monetary models, to “eliminate one market by Walras Law” and add a “money market” is correct.

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Appendix: The Inconsistency of the Neoclassical Dichotomy ■Under an institutionally correct setup of money supply, the classical assumption of degree 0 homogeneity in money prices of the demand and supply functions, ■leads to a logical contradiction as the following shows: Starting with a general market equilibrium so that following eq. (3):

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Appendix: The Inconsistency of the Neoclassical Dichotomy ■A multiplication of all money prices by a factor λ ≠ 1 yields: ■Given the assumption of zero degree homogenty in money prices this equals ■what contradicts the assumption that λ ≠ 1. = 0 = M S

© Prof. Dr. Rainer Maurer Literature For a detailed paper with an extension of the argument to a DSGE- Model see: