Intra-household Allocation Conflict and Cooperation in the Family.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Advertisements

Are you a Rotten Kid? Household decision-making Ruth Tarrant.
Drug Consumption and Intra-household Distribution of Resources: The Case of Khat in Djibouti Seminar Federico Perali Department of Economics University.
Fairness and Social Welfare Functions. Deriving the Utility Possibility Frontier (UPF) We begin with the Edgeworth Box that starts with individual 1,and.
AAEC 2305 Fundamentals of Ag Economics Chapter 2 Economics of Demand.
Income effect is the effect on the quantity demanded of the commodity due to the change in the income of the consumer while the prices of the other commodities.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics
Indifference Curves and
Identifying Non-Cooperative Behavior Among Spouses: Child Outcomes in Migrant-Sending Households Session 4E: Growth, Jobs and Earnings May 15, 2008 Joyce.
Consumer Theory.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Calculate and graph a budget line that shows the.
Spending time and money within the household Martin Browning University of Oxford Mette Gørtz AKF, Copenhagen IFS Family Workshop, September 2006.
1 Chapter 3 – Tools of Normative Analysis Public Finance McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
General Equilibrium and Efficiency. General Equilibrium Analysis is the study of the simultaneous determination of prices and quantities in all relevant.
12 Consumer Choice and Demand
11 PART 4 Consumer Choice and Demand A CLOSER LOOK AT DECISION MAKERS
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Household Production and Life-Cycle and Labor Supply
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
Part 2 Demand © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Changes in Income An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel manner An increase in income will cause the budget constraint.
Benefit Cost Analysis and the Entanglements of Love Ted Bergstrom, UCSB.
CH 6. SUPPLY OF LABOR TO THE ECONOMY: THE DECISION TO WORK
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
Economic Theories of Fertility Beyond Malthus. Thomas Malthus (early 19C) fertility determined by the age at marriage and frequency of coition during.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Home Production Defined Home production - purposeful activities performed in individual households that result in goods and services that enable a family.
1. The Market Economy Fall Outline A. Introduction: What is Efficiency? B. Supply and Demand (1 Market) C. Efficiency of Consumption (Many Markets)
Utility Maximization and Choice
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 15-1 Chapter Fifteen Wage and Employment Determination Under Collective Bargaining Modeified from slides created by: Erica Morrill.
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
Consumer behaviorslide 1 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Preferences. The conflict between opportunities and desires. Utility maximizing behavior.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
PART 7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Chapter 2 Labor Supply.
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Review of the previous lecture A consumer’s budget constraint shows the possible combinations of different goods he can buy given his income and the prices.
LABOR SUPPLY I. Consumer theory II. Labor supply by individuals III. What happens when wages change IV. Elasticity of labor supply.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Economics Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2015 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London.
Objectives:  Use the utility-maximizing model to explain how consumers choose goods and services.  Use the concept of utility to explain how the law.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand 10 The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand The theory of.
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Utility- is the satisfaction you receive from consuming a good or service Total utility is the number of units of utility that a consumer gains from consuming.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Chapter 16 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency.
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Household Production and Life- Cycle and Labor Supply.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
Chapter 6. Supply of Labor to the Economy Importance of Labor Supply 1) Any country ’ s well-being in the long run heavily depends on the willingness of.
Chapter 3 - Tools of Normative Analysis
CH 6. SUPPLY OF LABOR TO THE ECONOMY: THE DECISION TO WORK
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
WELFARE FOUNDATION OF CBA
Presentation transcript:

Intra-household Allocation Conflict and Cooperation in the Family

Non-cooperation as a starting point Assume that each person will act to maximize their welfare as they evaluate it, given the predicted behaviour of others. A “Nash equilibrium” is, in its essence, the general formulation of this assumption. Provides a foundation for modelling cooperative behaviour within a family.

Basic model Focuses on the behaviour of couples with children. Expenditures on children (G) are assumed to be a public good for the parents, but each parent has their own preferences. The preferences of each parent j are represented by the utility function: U j = U j (x j,G), where x j. is parent j’s private consumption.

Voluntary contributions to expenditures on children, G g j (g j  0), and so x j = y j - g j and G= (g 1 +g 2 )/p, where y j is the income of parent j and p is the price of the child good relative to that of the private good, x j.

Nash equilibrium Each parent chooses their contribution to child expenditures to maximize their utility, taking the contribution of their partner as given; that is, parent j chooses g j to maximize U j (y j -g j, (g 1 +g 2 )/p), subject to g j  0. Implies U jG (x j *, G*)/U jx (x j *, G*)  p, j=1,2.

Solution If U jG (x j *, G*)/U jx (x j *, G*) = p for both parents, it provides two equations in g 1 and g 2, which describe their strategies, and these can be solved for the Nash equilibrium contribution. If U jG (x j *, G*)/U jx (x j *, G*) < p for parent j (he/she is ‘too poor’), their contribution is zero.

Example: U j =  j ln(x j ) + (1-  j )ln(G), When g 1 >0 and g 2 >0 and p=1, (2a) g 1 = (1-  1 )y 1 - (  1 g 2 ) (2b) g 2 = (1-  2 )y 2 - (  2 g 1 ) Nash equilibrium illustrated in Figure 2.1, with  1 >  2

Example solutions (3a)g 1N = [(1-  1 )y 1 -  1 (1-  2 )y 2 ]/(1-  1  2 ) (3b)g 2N = [(1-  2 )y 2 -  2 (1-  1 )y 1 ]/(1-  1  2 ) The contribution of parent j is increasing in their income and decreasing in the other parent’s. From equations (3), (4a)G N = [(1-  1 )(1-  2 )(y 1 +y 2 )]/(1-  1  2 ) (4b)x 1N = [  1 (1-  2 )(y 1 +y 2 )]/(1-  1  2 ) (4c)x 2N = [  2 (1-  1 )(y 1 +y 2 )]/(1-  1  2 )

When both parents contribute Non-cooperative outcomes only depend on the joint income of the parents, y 1 +y 2. E.g. in example, (4a)G N = [(1-  1 )(1-  2 )(y 1 +y 2 )]/(1-  1  2 ) (4b)x 1N = [  1 (1-  2 )(y 1 +y 2 )]/(1-  1  2 ) (4c)x 2N = [  2 (1-  1 )(y 1 +y 2 )]/(1-  1  2 )

Only one parent contributing Taking the father as parent 1, he will not contribute when y 1 /(y 1 +y 2 ) <  1 (1-  2 )/(1-  1  2 ) In this case, G N =(1-  2 )y 2, x 1N =y 1 and x 2N =  2 y 2. Analogously, for the mother—see Fig. 2.2 Individual incomes matter for the outcome.

Non-Cooperative Equilibrium The non-cooperative equilibrium can indicate: what the “fallback position” would be if communication and bargaining within the family break down; how individual preferences and incomes affect this fallback position.

‘Separate spheres’ non-cooperative model (Lundberg and Pollack) Two household public goods. High costs of the coordination that would be required for choices about voluntary contributions to public goods based on relative preferences and incomes. Traditional gender roles provide a focal point that avoids coordination problems: Man decides about one, the woman about the other; ‘social prescribed’ spheres of influence.

‘Separate spheres’ implications Reaction functions analogous to earlier, in which the man’s demand functions depend on the purchases of the ‘woman’s public good’ and vice versa. Nash equilibrium: intersection of the two public good demand functions. Non-cooperative equilibrium allocation depends on individual incomes, y 1 and y 2.

Low coordination costs Outcomes are purely determined by preferences and relative incomes. There is at most one public good to which both will contribute (Browning et al). When the intra-family income distribution is such that there is such a public good, individual incomes do not matter for outcomes. When parents’ incomes are ‘very similar’, each contributes to a different public good—looks like ‘separate spheres’ model.

Cooperative Equilibrium Cooperation between parents to achieve an allocation between parents’ private consumption and child expenditure such that one parent cannot be made better off without making the other worse off; i.e. a Pareto-efficient allocation. must maximize U 1 (x 1, G) subject to: (a) U 2 (x 2, G)  U 2 * and (b) y 1 + y 2 = x 1 + x 2 + pG

Equivalent Formulation Equivalently, it must maximize U 1 (x 1, G) +  U 2 (x 2, G) subject to constraint (b), where  is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the “efficiency constraint” (a). This is what Chiappori (1992) calls the “collective” approach (model).

Cooperative solution Maximisation implies that: U 1x (x 1 e, G e )=  U 2x (x 2 e, G e ) p = U 1G (x 1 e, G e )/U 1x (x 1 e, G e ) + U 2G (x 2 e, G e )/U 2x (x 2 e, G e ) i.e. the Samuelson (1954) condition for the efficient provision of public goods. Cf. U jG (x j *, G*)/U jx (x j *, G*) = p in Nash equilibrium→ inefficiency.

Utility possibility frontier The locus of Pareto optimal utility levels for the two parents corresponding to given values of y 1, y 2, p and the parameters of their utility functions. Different  imply different positions on frontier.

Demand functions G=G e (y 1 +y 2, p,  ) x j =x j e (y 1 +y 2, p,  ), j=1,2 In general,  is a function of individual incomes and the price of the public good; i.e.  =  (y 1,y 2,p) Cooperation and efficiency are indicated by the presence of this common (unknown) function in all the demand functions.

Cross-equation restrictions Because  G/  y j =(  G e /  )(  /  y j ), j=1,2, and similarly for x j, (  G/  y 1 )/(  G/  y 2 )=(  /  y 1 )/(  /  y 2 )= (  x 1 /  y 1 )/(  x 1 /  y 2 )=(  x 2 /  y 1 )/(  x 2 /  y 2 ) i.e. the marginal propensities to consume out of different sources of income must be proportional to each other across all of the goods. Provides a test of intra-family efficiency.

Example: utility functions used earlier pG e = [(1-  1 )+  (1-  2 )](y 1 +y 2 )/(1+  ) x 1 e =  1 (y 1 +y 2 )/(1+  ) x 2 e =  2 (y 1 +y 2 )/(1+  ). Equivalent to giving each parent a share of joint income, 1/(1+  ) and  /(1+  ) respectively, and letting each choose according to their own preferences. An income “sharing rule” (Chiappori 1992).

Income effects Possible interpretation of  (y 1,y 2,p) is that it reflects bargaining in the family, with  increasing in y 2 and decreasing in y 1. Define  =  /(1+  ); then in example,  G e /  y 2 ={[(1-  )(1-  1 )+  (1-  2 )] + (y 1 +y 2 )(  1 -  2 )(  /  y 2 )}/p  x 2 e /  y 2 =  2 + (y 1 +y 2 )  2 (  /  y 2 )

Two effects of mother’s income (y 2 ) on child expenditure (G): 1.It increases family income (y 1 +y 2 ); (1-  )(1-  1 )+  (1-  2 ) in example. 2.It may increase mother’s bargaining power (  /  y 2 >0); (y 1 +y 2 )(  1 -  2 )(  /  y 2 ) in example could reinforce (  1 >  2 ) or offset (  1 <  2 ) the income effect.

Distribution factors Variables that affect the intra-family decision process (i.e.  ) without affecting individual preferences or resources. These may include marriage market attributes and divorce laws that, in some circumstances, affect bargaining between spouses within marriage. Also, person’s share of household income.

Inferences about individual welfare Suppose we can observe x 1 and x 2 separately (often can only observe x 1 +x 2 ); i.e. man and woman consume some different goods (e.g. men’s and women’s clothing). Let  be dependent on mother’s income share, s 2 =y 2 /(y 1 +y 2 ). From above, holding y 1 +y 2 constant,  x 2 e /  s 2 =(y 1 +y 2 )  2 (  /  y 2 ) E.g. if  /  y 2 >0, higher s 2 increases x 2 and, conditional on G, the mother’s welfare.

‘Caring’ preferences Preferences take the form V 1 = V 1 [U 1 (x 1,G), U 2 (x 2,G)], and similarly for parent 2, where the U j (  ) are “private” utility indices for each parent and V j [  ] is “social utility” to parent j A natural way to represent parents caring for each other (i.e.  V j /  U k >0 for j  k). If V j =U j (x j,G), then these preferences collapse to egoistic ones.

Implications Demand functions of the same general form as above. –Any outcome that is efficient in the context of caring preferences would also be efficient if the parents were egoistic. Points A and B in Figure are best choices under caring—the indifference curves associated with V 2 (U 1,U 2 ) and V 1 (U 1,U 2 ) respectively are tangent to the utility possibility frontier. Caring preferences eliminate two segments at the extremes of the frontier because parents who care for one another do not want their partner’s ‘private’ utility to fall below some minimum level. – above A and below B, only joint income matters.

Bargaining within Families Noted that  may reflect bargaining, but a bargaining theory was not advanced. Each partner has the alternative of not cooperating, providing an alternative level of utility, which we call their threat points. Possible cooperative solutions lie on UPF, between the two threat points, T 1 and T 2.

Bargaining rules Dominant partner--couple maximizes his or her utility. –E.g. father dominant, solution is D A in figure –he would offer his wife just enough to accept this arrangement—her threat point. Nash bargaining: maximizes the product of the gains from cooperation, where these gains are U 1 -T 1 and U 2 -T 2 —NB A in Figure. Effect of change in threat point—Figure.

What should be the threat point? Rubinstein-Binmore multi-period bargaining game. Partners alternate in proposing how to “divide the cake”: utility from cooperation in the family which we normalise to be 1. i.e. u 1 +u 2 =1, where u j is the proposed utility of partner j in marriage. In any period in which they remain married but do not reach an agreement, partner j receives utility b j.

Equilibrium of bargaining game b 1 +b 2 <1 due to inefficiency of non-cooperation. If either partner asks for a divorce, they will get m 1 and m 2 respectively, where m 1 +m 2 <1. If the time between offers is “small”, the unique equilibrium of the bargaining process is u j e = b j + (1-b 1 -b 2 )/2, j=1,2; that is, the gains from cooperative relative to non-cooperative marriage are shared equally. Three cases.

Three cases a)b j + (1-b 1 -b 2 )/2 > m j, j=1,2 Divorce threat not credible for either party b)b 1 + (1-b 1 -b 2 )/2 < m 1, Divorce threat is credible for the husband and u 1 e =m 1 and u 2 e =1-m 1 >m 2 c)b 2 + (1-b 1 -b 2 )/2 < m 2 Divorce threat is credible for the wife and u 1 e =1-m 2 >m 1 and u 2 e =m 2

Threat points and non-cooperative marriage Suppose divorce threat is not credible. Then Non-cooperative marriage provides threat point (i.e. b 1 and b 2 above). Does individual income affect threat point? No, when both contribute to the public good in ‘voluntary contributions’ formulation above (i.e. when their incomes are ‘similar’). Yes, in ‘voluntary contributions’ formulation when incomes are sufficiently ‘dissimilar’. Yes, in ‘separate spheres’ formulation.

Home production Explicit treatment of household production is standard in family economics. Consider a very simple home production technology in which each parent may contribute time (t j ) to the raising of their children: G= h 1 t 1 + h 2 t 2 where h j is the productivity of j’s time. Have replaced purchases of G with home production of it.

Non-cooperative equilibrium Even if parents do not cooperate, it may be in the interest of one parent to make financial transfers to the other. Private consumption of the mother is given by x 2 = (T-t 2 )w 2 + y 2 + s 1, where T is total time available, w j is parent j’s wage, y j is j’s non-labour income and s 1 is transfers from the father to the mother. Analogous for father.

Mother’s decision Assume the mother chooses her time allocation, t 2, to maximize her utility, taking the time allocation of her husband and the financial transfer from him as given. She chooses t 2 to maximize U 2 ((T-t 2 )w 2 + y 2 + s 1, h 1 t 1 + h 2 t 2 ), which implies U 2G (x 2 *,G*)/U 2x (x 2 *,G*) = w 2 /h 2 LHS is MRS and RHS is MC.

Mother’s reaction function With the Cobb-Douglas utility function assumed earlier, this condition, the budget constraint and the home production technology implies that her reaction function is t 2 = (1-  2 )[(w 2 T+y 2 +s 1 )/w 2 )] -  2 h 1 t 1 /h 2 Best strategy: reduce her home production time when father increases his.

Father’s decision He chooses his time allocation and monetary transfers to his wife, s 1, so as to maximize his utility, U 1 ((T-t 1 )w 1 + y 1 -s 1, h 1 t 1 +h 2 t 2 ), subject to: Mother’s reaction function t 1  0, s 1  0 Implies two conditions: w 1 /(1-  2 )h 1  U 1G (x 1 *,G*)/U 1x (x 1 *,G*) = (1-  1 )x 1 /  1 G w 2 /(1-  2 )h 2  U 1G (x 1 *,G*)/U 1x (x 1 *,G*) = (1-  1 )x 1 /  1 G

Non-cooperative Equilibrium Both cannot hold with equality if w 2 /h 2  w 1 /h 1. If, for example, w 2 /h 2 0. i.e. full specialisation in market work by the father (note: mother may also work in market). He effectively buys the time of the mother through voluntary transfers.

Voluntary transfers and ‘income pooling’ equilibrium Transfer from the father to the mother is s 1 = (1-  1 )(w 1 T+y 1 )-  1 (w 2 T+y 2 ) i.e. transfer rises with his ‘full income (w 1 T+y 1 ) and declines with hers (w 2 T+y 2 ). Family full income: Y F =(w 1 +w 2 )T+y 1 +y 2 G N = (1-  1 )(1-  2 )Y F /(w 2 /h 2 ) x 1 =  1 Y F and x 2 =  2 (1-  1 )Y F.

When intra-family income distribution matters If neither condition above holds with equality, s 1 =0 and t 1 =0. Father finds the child good too expensive. Occurs when (w 2 T+y 2 )/(w 1 T+y 1 )>(1-  1 )/  1 ; Father is ‘too poor’ relative to the mother. G N = (1-  2 )(w 2 T+y 2 )/(w 2 /h 2 ). Redistribution of income from father to mother raises G N and x 2 and lowers x 1.

Transfers and income pooling When w 2 /h 2 < w 1 /h 1, the mother will never make financial transfers to the father. She has the comparative advantage in child rearing. Who, if anyone, makes transfers depends on the relative cost of the child good as well as relative full incomes. Non-cooperative outcome may provide the threat points for cooperative bargaining.

Specialisation The tendency for one or both parents to specialise fully is a reflection of the particular production technology assumed. It may not hold with diminishing marginal productivity of each parent’s time input.

Effects of parents’ wages when w 2 /h 2 <w 1 /h 1, Increases in the mother’s wage (w 2 ) give rise to both a substitution effect and an income effect on provision of the child good. Increases in the father’s wage (w 1 ) only affect the provision of the child good through an income effect; and there would be no effect of w 1 (or y 1 ) if the father does not make transfers to his partner. Higher productivity in child rearing for the mother (i.e. higher h 2 ) raises G N.

Cooperative equilbrium Full specialisation in market work by one parent if w 2 /h 2  w 1 /h 1. If w 2 /h 2 < w 1 /h 1, then t 1 =0 and w 2 /h 2 = U 1G (x 1 *,G*)/U 1x (x 1 *,G*) + U 2G (x 2 *,G*)/U 2x (x 2 *,G*) (Samuelson cond.) Analogous to earlier formulation with p=w 2 /h 2 and family full income Y F replacing “y 1 +y 2 ”. Mother’s wage has a substitution effect, as well as income and bargaining effects.