Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Last 2 weeks of teaching Today: lecture 33 on Public Goods. Tomorrow: lecture 34 on Asymmetric Information. Next Monday: last.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
4. Public Goods.
Advertisements

18 chapter: >> Public Goods and Common Resources Krugman/Wells
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.
PART 10 Market Failures Markets may fail to generate efficient results due to Monopoly Externalities Public Goods Open Access Markets may also have informational.
Lecture 3 Public Goods and Government intervention
Social Choice Session 9 Carmen Pasca and John Hey.
Public Goods and Tax Policy
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. u 35: Public Goods u 36: Asymmetric Information u 17: Auctions u 33: Law & Economics u 34: Information Technology u.
Nash’s Theorem Theorem (Nash, 1951): Every finite game (finite number of players, finite number of pure strategies) has at least one mixed-strategy Nash.
1 Predatory Conduct. 2 Predatory conduct is the implementation of a strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. To.
Chapter 36 Public Goods Suppose there are two nonsmokers and one smoker. Even if nonsmokers are entitled to clean air, they first have to agree among themselves.
Lecture 5.
Government Policy and Market Failures
Voting for Public Goods (Fisher, Ch. 3) © Allen C. Goodman 2015.
Variable Public Good Quantities E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park.
Public Goods Public goods are extreme cases of externalities, where all consumers can enjoy the good even if they don’t pay for it. A pure public good,
ECO 230 Principles of Economics I: Microeconomics Chapter I J.F. O’Connor 1/19/05.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
Expectations and our IS-LM model In this lecture we will examine how expectations about the future will impact investment and consumption today. We will.
Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Law and Economics-Charles W. Upton Hicks-Kaldor Optimality.
Agent Technology for e-Commerce Chapter 10: Mechanism Design Maria Fasli
1 Basic Macroeconomic Relationships. 2 Overview Here we study some basic economic relationships that we think hold in a general way in the economy. Here.
Chapter 7 The Costs and Benefits of a franchise to a city 1.
Externalities Game Rules  Work in pairs.  Everyone who is sitting on the odd row represents Firm A.  Those who are sitting on the even row represent.
ECO 120 Macroeconomics Week 2 Aggregate Expenditures Model Lecturer Dr. Rod Duncan.
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
Microeconomics 2 Lecture 2 Gains from exchange. Who will win the Nobel Prize in economics in 2013? In below Al Roth Lloyd Shapley See the Guardian.
Voting for Public Goods (Fisher, Ch. 3) © Allen C. Goodman 2009.
Source: Mankiw (2000) Macroeconomics, Chapter 3 p Determinants of Demand for Goods and Services Examine: how the output from production is used.
Chapter 30: The Labor Market Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
ECMB36 LECTURE NOTES MEASURING CHANGES IN SOCIAL WELFARE Townley, Chapter 5.
Public Policy Analysis MPA 404 Lecture 21. Previous Lecture Distribution of resources as a rationale for policy interventions The Social Welfare Function.
Please open your laptops and pull up Quiz Only the provided online calculator may be used on this quiz. You may use your yellow formula sheet for.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 20-1 CHAPTER 20 Public Goods and Common Resources PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers,
Theme 4 - Public Goods Public Economics.
© 2010 Pearson Education CanadaChapter Chapter 10 Acid Rain on Others’ Parades © 2010 Pearson Education Canada.
McTaggart, Findlay, Parkin: Microeconomics © 2007 Pearson Education Australia Chapter 5: Efficiency and Equity.
Economics for Leaders Lesson 8: Setting the Rules - Costs and Benefits of Government Action.
Spreadsheets in Finance and Forecasting Presentation 8: Problem Solving.
Social Choice Session 7 Carmen Pasca and John Hey.
Interest ratesslide 1 INTEREST RATE DETERMINATION The rate of interest is the price of money to borrow and lend. Rates of interest are expressed as decimals.
PARETO OPTIMALITY AND THE EFFICIENCY GOAL
1 Externalities. 2 Externalities  Externalities are a market failure (so Government intervention may be advisable).  Externalities imply that there.
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Microeconomics Lecture 2 Gains from exchange. Attention! I am giving each of you a piece of paper. On it is written information useful to you and private.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Game theory (and a bit of bargaining theory) A homage to John Nash. Born Still alive (as far as Google knows). Spent.
Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u Public goods involve a particular kind of externality - where the same amount of the good has to be available.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Examinations Go to Read.
Extending the Definition of Exponents © Math As A Second Language All Rights Reserved next #10 Taking the Fear out of Math 2 -8.
Auction Theory תכנון מכרזים ומכירות פומביות Topic 7 – VCG mechanisms 1.
Lecture 13 Externalities, public goods, common-property resources.
Finding an exponential growth or decay equation (6.14)
1 University of Auckland Winter Week Lectures Second Lecture 3 July 2007 Associate Professor Ananish Chaudhuri Department of Economics University of Auckland.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Game Theory: Basics MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell March 2004.
Mechanism Design II CS 886:Electronic Market Design Sept 27, 2004.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Next two lectures The lectures tomorrow (Tuesday the 22 nd of January) and next Monday (the 28 nd of January) will be on examination.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Public Goods. 2 Consider an unregulated world, where a firm has the implicit property rights to the air. Therefore, it is.
Public Goods and Common Resources Chapter 17. A way to classify goods that predicts whether a good is a private good—a good that can be efficiently provided.
 Public Goods In Networks Ryan Dewar. What is a public good  Public goods have two distinct aspects:  Non-excludable: The cost of keeping nonpayers.
Warm Up  Suppose your sibling or friend owed you $500.  Would you rather have this money repaid to you right away, in one payment, or spread out over.
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
Introduction to Economics What do you think of when you think of economics?
Copyright©2004 South-Western 11 Public Goods and Common Resource.
Week 1 Real Numbers and Their Properties (Section 1.6, 1.7, 1.8)
Chapter 36 Public Goods.
Eco 3311 Lecture 12 One Period Closed Economy Model - Equilibrium
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods.
Chapter 37 Public Goods Key Concept: Free Riding.
Presentation transcript:

Microeconomics 2 John Hey

Last 2 weeks of teaching Today: lecture 33 on Public Goods. Tomorrow: lecture 34 on Asymmetric Information. Next Monday: last 11 questions on first specimen examination paper. Next Tuesday: Question and Answer session. Please send me your queries and questions in advance. In the two meetings next term I will go through the second specimen paper. I will tell you the material strengthening the exam.

Lecture 33: Public Goods A public good is one that everyone can consume simultaneously; one person’s consumption of it does not reduce the consumption of others. For example: a public park, a television channel, clean air, national defense. There are not many examples of pure public goods, but we shall here assume one of them. We can have “all or nothing” public goods. And also variable-level public goods. I don’t like the analysis of Public Goods.

Why I do not like the economic study of public goods Economic analysis seems totally negative: It shows that private provision of public goods is either non- existent or inadequate, because people free-ride on others and (have incentives to) hide their true preferences for the good. Methods (which could be used by the state) to incentivise people to reveal their true preferences (such as voting or the Groves- Clarke mechanism) have deep flaws. We almost certainly end up with public/State provision. (What the state ‘should do’ takes us into Social Choice and the problems of aggregating preferences.) Is this surprising? Note there are very few examples of the private provision of public goods. (?? Clubs, closed societies of various forms.)

A pretend experiment Every one of you can contribute £10 or nothing. I will count up the contributions and I will add an equal amount to the total contributed: this is the public fund. This public fund will be distributed equally to all of you. Let us play this – but pretend it is for real. When I ask you, you should put up your hands if you want to contribute £10.

Two examples First example: Suppose there are 200 students here and 30 of them contribute £10 and the other 170 nothing. The public fund is thus £600 = £300 from the students and £300 from me. Every student gets £3. But note that the 30 students who contributed £10 end up £7 worse off than when they started, while the 170 who contributed nothing end up £3 better off than when they started. Second example: Suppose there are 200 students here and 70 of them contribute £10 and the other 130 nothing. The public fund is thus £1400 = £700 from the students and £700 from me. Every student gets £7. But note that the 70 students who contributed £10 end up £3 worse off than when they started, while the 130 who contributed nothing end up £7 better off than when they started.

Two more (extreme) examples Third example: Suppose there are 200 students here and all of them contribute £10. The public fund is thus £4000 = £2000 from the students and £2000 from me. Every student gets £20. So they are all £10 better off than at the beginning. Fourth example: Suppose there are 200 students here and all of them contribute nothing. The public fund is thus zero. Every student gets nothing – but no-one has paid anything. Let us do it (but not for real).

The Public Good problem the table shows the payoffs relative to the starting position (200 students) Each of 199 others AB Me A(£0,£0) (£19.90,£9.90) B (-£9.90,£0.10)(£10.00,£10.00) A: Contribute zero B: Contribute £10

Overview of the problem (suppose 100 people) Everyone is invited to contribute to the public good. Total contributions are doubled and divided equally amongst the members of society. Every £1 more that I contribute I get back 2p but I have spent £1 so I am a 98p out of pocket. But if everyone contributes £1 more everyone is £1 better off (taking into account the contribution). Similarly for every £1 less that I contribute I lose 2p and so I save 98p. If everyone contributes £1 less then everyone is £1 worse off.

Connection with public goods We have portrayed the above problem as an all-or- nothing problem for the individual but it is variable in total. As we have seen, if contributions are voluntary, then everyone would prefer everyone else to pay and it might not get provided at all. Depends upon the provision rules. Let us look more at a variable-level public good. This is where individuals can contribute varying amounts. But let us take a more general problem – with two goods - instead of just having money. So all (both) citizens are deciding between two goods, a private one and a public one. Let us go to Maple (skip the first section)...

The next 9 slides In black and white, are shamelessly downloaded from Martin Cripps site at UCL. My thanks to him. Back to all-or-nothing. Reveals how clever economists (think they) are.

Clark-Groves Mechanism This is a process that will get individuals to truthfully to reveal their preferences for the public good. Step 1 : Individuals report their value for the bridge (the public good) v i Note : they don’t have to report the truth v i ≠ v i *

Clark-Groves Mechanism This is a process that will get individuals to truthfully to reveal their preferences for the public good. Step 1 : Individuals report their value for the bridge v i Step 2 : Add up the reported values.

Clark-Groves Mechanism This is a process that will get individuals to truthfully to reveal their preferences for the public good. Step 1 : Individuals report their value for the bridge v i Step 2 : Add up the reported values. Step 3 : If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge > 0 then build the bridge.

Clark-Groves Mechanism This is a process that will get individuals to truthfully to reveal their preferences for the public good. Step 1 : Individuals report their value for the bridge v i Step 2 : Add up the reported values. Step 3 : If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge > 0 Build Bridge If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge <0 Do not Build

Clark-Groves Mechanism Step 1 : Individuals report their value for the bridge v i Step 2 : Add up the reported values. Step 3 : If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge >0 Build Bridge If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge <0 Don’t Build Step 4 : If the individual’s value was decisive, i.e. Sum of Others’ Reports < Cost of Bridge < Sum of all Reports

Clark-Groves Mechanism Step 1 : Individuals report their value for the bridge v i Step 2 : Add up the reported values. Step 3 : If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge >0 Build Bridge If Sum of reported values – Cost of Bridge <0 Don’t Build Step 4 : If the individual’s value was decisive, i.e. Sum of Others’ Reports < Cost of Bridge < Sum of all Reported values Charge the individual = Cost of Bridge – Sum of others’ reported values

Clark-Groves Mechanism Optimal to tell the truth. Let U be the sum of the other’s reports and let v be my value. If U>Cost: I don’t care what I say so reporting truthfully is fine.

Clark-Groves Mechanism Optimal to tell the truth. If U+v > Cost > U: Then any report u such that U+u>Cost (or u>Cost-U) will get me utility v – (Cost –U) >0. (independent of report!) But any report u < Cost – U will get me utility =0. To ensure I get this positive utility should then report truthfully.

Clark-Groves Mechanism Properties: (1)Optimal to tell the truth (2)Voter only pays when decisive. (3)Payments < benefits received (4)As population grows less of a problem with excess revenue.

Groves-Clark mechanism – to decide whether an all-or-nothing public should be provided Three flatmates – should they get a TV (costing £300)? The share of the costs has already been decided and the only question is whether it should be bought. Note that the sum of reservation values > cost. The pivotal person (here C) pays the tax – which would compensate the others if it were paid. But it cannot be – as it would destroy the incentive for everyone to reveal their true reservation values. PersonCost shareTrue Reservation value – stated as such Net value Clarke tax A£100£50-£50£0 B£100£50-£50£0 C£100£250£150£100

Summary A public good is a good that can be consumed simultaneously by more than one individual. Whether with an all-or-nothing public good or a variable public good there are difficulties in deciding who will/should pay for the good. There are clear individual incentives for individuals to free-ride. The Nash Equilibrium is clearly Pareto inferior to the Social optimum. Perhaps we should rely on state/public provision? But what is the State for?!

Lecture 33 Goodbye!