1 Nobody to play with? The implications of leisure coordination Stephen P. Jenkins ISER, University of Essex, UK Lars Osberg.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
© 2002 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Ltd.Chapter 4-1 Labour Supply Over the Life-cycle Chapter Four Created by: Erica Morrill, M.Ed Fanshawe College.
Advertisements

Random Assignment Experiments
Labor-Leisure Choice – Indifference Curves Graph by Harcourt, Inc. Just like the indifference curves used to derive consumer demand. Tradeoff is between.
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Heterogeneity One limitation of the static LS model lies in the heterogeneity assumption. In reality, individuals differ in preference and in information.
Spending time and money within the household Martin Browning University of Oxford Mette Gørtz AKF, Copenhagen IFS Family Workshop, September 2006.
ELM Part 2- Economic models Manuela Samek
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
Productivity, Output, and Employment
A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment
Search and Unemploy-ment
Household Production and Life-Cycle and Labor Supply
Trends in Corporate Governance Benjamin E. Hermalin UC Berkeley.
CH. 8: THE ECONOMY AT FULL EMPLOYMENT: THE CLASSICAL MODEL
Labor Market Overview (Part 2). The Labor Market Labor markets determine –Terms of employment Earnings versus total compensation Working conditions –Levels.
Chapter 2 – Tools of Positive Analysis
IFS Did the Working Families’ Tax Credit work? Analysing the impact of in-work support on labour supply and programme participation Mike Brewer, Alan Duncan,
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
Chapter 16 Unemployment: Search and Efficiency Wages.
Do Friends and Relatives Really Help in Getting a Good Job? Michele Pellizzari London School of Economics.
Home Production Defined Home production - purposeful activities performed in individual households that result in goods and services that enable a family.
1 “Keeping in Touch” - A Benefit of Public Holidays Joachim Merz Department of Economics and Social Sciences University of Lüneburg
Economics of Gender Chapter 5 Assist.Prof.Dr.Meltem INCE YENILMEZ.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
Chapter 3 Productivity, Output, and Employment Copyright © 2012 Pearson Education Inc.
Modelling the labour market Labour supply decisions The effect of a minimum wage.
Economics of Gender Chapter 5 Assist.Prof.Dr.Meltem INCE YENILMEZ.
1 “Keeping in Touch” - A Benefit of Public Holidays Joachim Merz Department of Economics and Social Sciences University of Lüneburg
1 Ch. 7. At Full Employment: The Classical Model The relationship between the quantity of labor employed and real GDP What determines the full-employment.
Off-farm labour participation of farmers and spouses Alessandro Corsi University of Turin.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2002 Week 8 Introduction to macroeconomics.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
PART 7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
Chapter 2 Labor Supply.
Labor Supply (Static) Chapter 2.
Lecture 13: Expanding the Model with Labour Supply L11200 Introduction to Macroeconomics 2009/10 Reading: Barro Ch.8 22 February 2010.
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
Childcare availability and female labor supply Anna Lovasz - Agnes Szabo-Morvai The impact of day-care services on mothers’ employment, fertility, and.
LABOR SUPPLY I. Consumer theory II. Labor supply by individuals III. What happens when wages change IV. Elasticity of labor supply.
Supply of Labor. How do We Spend our Time? Working, playing, sleeping, eating, travelling, working out Simplify: work and leisure Time spent working is.
Next page Chapter 2: The Theory of Individual Labor Supply.
Chapter 5 Compensating Wage Differentials Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
HAOMING LIU JINLI ZENG KENAN ERTUNC GENETIC ABILITY AND INTERGENERATIONAL EARNINGS MOBILITY 1.
Kelly McCrudden Jessica Crawford George Findlay Pamela Ho Schirle, T Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 26, No. 4 (October 2008), pp
Labour Supply and Inequality Trends in the U.S.A. & elsewhere Lars Osberg Department of Economics Dalhousie University
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice
Productivity, Output, and Employment
Nobody to Play With - Labour Supply and Inequality Trends in the U.S.A. and elsewhere Lars Osberg Department of Economics Dalhousie University
Tasks and Opportunities Within Indian Families Sripad Motiram Lars Osberg Department of Economics, Dalhousie University, Halifax Canadian Economics Association.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Time, Money and Inequality in International Perspective Lars Osberg -Dalhousie University -I.S.E.R. U of Essex.
Topic 8 Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS-LM model
1 Household Interaction Impact on Married Female Labor Supply Zvi Eckstein and Osnat Lifshitz.
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Modern Labour Economics Chapter 7 Labour Supply: Household Production, the Family, and the Life Cycle.
1/53: Topic 3.1 – Models for Ordered Choices Microeconometric Modeling William Greene Stern School of Business New York University New York NY USA William.
The Labour Market Academic year 2015/16 Introduction to Economics Augusto Ninni.
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 6 Chapter Household Behavior.
6. Ordered Choice Models. Ordered Choices Ordered Discrete Outcomes E.g.: Taste test, credit rating, course grade, preference scale Underlying random.
Household Production and Life- Cycle and Labor Supply.
[Part 5] 1/43 Discrete Choice Modeling Ordered Choice Models Discrete Choice Modeling William Greene Stern School of Business New York University 0Introduction.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
Assessing the Impact of Informality on Wages in Tanzania: Is There a Penalty for Women? Pablo Suárez Robles (University Paris-Est Créteil) 1.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
Maternal Movements into Part time Employment: What is the Penalty? Jenny Willson, Department of Economics, University of Sheffield.
Search and Unemploy-ment
Compensating Wage Differentials
The Theory of Individual Labor Supply
Heterogeneity One limitation of the static LS model lies in the heterogeneity assumption. In reality, individuals differ in preference and in information.
Presentation transcript:

1 Nobody to play with? The implications of leisure coordination Stephen P. Jenkins ISER, University of Essex, UK Lars Osberg Economics Department, Dalhousie University, Canada

2 The paper in one slide The core hypothesis: –Each individual’s time use choices are contingent on the time use choices of others –The utility derived from leisure time often benefits from the presence of companionable others (an externality argument) The paper presents: –A model of time use, and –Shows that it is consistent with the behaviour of British working couples in the 1990s

3 The core hypothesis What people do in their non-work time … –often involves other people –often distinctly more pleasurable if done with others –often impossible without others Heterogeneity of leisure tastes means that individuals face the problem of locating Suitable Leisure Companions – ‘somebody to play with’ – and of scheduling simultaneous free time  when paid work absorbs more of other people’s time, each person will find their own leisure time scheduling & matching problem more difficult to solve, –i.e. own leisure hours will be of less utility  externality to individual labour supply choices, implying possibility of multiple, sometimes Pareto-inferior, labour market equilibria

4 Relationship to literature Cf. standard household labour supply model (‘leisure time of husbands and wives as complementary goods’) Corneo (2001) re private & social leisure (TV); Weiss (1996) re work hour coordination; etc. Evidence of spousal synchronisation of work schedules (Hallberg, 2003, S; Hamermesh, 2002, USA; Sullivan, 1996, GB; van Velzen, 2001, NL) This paper: Model + Evidence about (1) spousal work synchronisation, and (2) the role of others outside the household (measures of Suitable Leisure Companion availability) in determining propensities for associative leisure activities

5 Outline Theoretical model illustrating idea of interdependencies of time use choices within and outside the household (Section 2) Overview of British Household Panel Survey data and key variables (Section 3) Preliminary evidence of externalities in likelihood of associational activity – social groups and sports clubs (Section 4) Synchronisation and scheduling of spousal work time – regressions (Section 5) Probability of engagement in associative leisure activities, and dependence of that of what others do – regressions (Section 6) Some implications: the welfare effects of longer work hours (Section 7)

6 The conventional model of time use Conventional unitary household model for couple: Max U = u(C, L m, L f ) subject to H m + L m = H f + L f = T C  w m H m + w f H f C = household goods consumption (assume there is a sharing rule); L m, L f = non-work time for husband and wife; H m, H f = work hours; w m, w f = hourly wages; T = total time available Optimal choice of work hours for husband (or wife):

7 Our model of time use choice Time use options: work (H hours), or non-work time spent either alone (A hours) or in social leisure (S hours). [Household production time ignored.] To enjoy social leisure, each individual must arrange a leisure match with some other individual (or group of individuals) from among the list of possible contacts that they have at the start of each period. Each period, individuals first must commit to specific duration & timing of work hours H, and then after that they arrange their social life H  household money income  utility from material consumption (via sharing rule) Ex ante, utility from social life is uncertain: –search for Suitable Leisure Companions involves uncertainty, since some desired matches may not be feasible. Time spent alone not working, A, is the residual after work and social commitments are honoured. U = u(C, A m, A f, S m0, S m1, …, S mn, S f0, S f1, …, S fn ) where i indexes possible Suitable Leisure Companions; social leisure time each partner spends with each other indexed by 0 (hence S m0 = S f0 ). Other social matches subscripted by 1,…,n and 1,…,n where n and n are the number of realized social leisure matches for each partner.

8 Solving the model of time use choice Arranging one’s social life cannot be done unilaterally –It involves a discrete matching process –It is constrained by the social contacts available to each person, and by the availability of other people. # social contacts/couple = k m + k f. Expected utility of specific social leisure match = p i u(S i ) –i indexes each potential SLC, p i is Pr(social match with i) and u(S i ) is utility associated with that match. Unitary couples maximise expected utility: max  (U) = u(C f ) + u(C m ) + p i0 [u m (S 0 ) + u f (S 0 )] +  i  km+kf { p im u m (S im ) + p if u f (S if )} + u Am [T – H f – p i0 u f (S i0 ) –  i  km+kf p im u m (S im ) ] + u Af [T – H m – p i0 u m (S i0 ) –  i  km+kf p if u f (S if ) ] where u Am and u Af are the utilities of non-work time spent alone.

9 Model equilibrium illustrated (for one of the spouses in a couple) Equilibrium requires work hours H* such that u* = MU H*, and A*, S* such that MU A* = MU S* = MU H*. MU S*, MU H* are ‘expected’ marginal utilities: uncertainty ex ante via p i = Pr(social match with i) p i is negatively associated with own work hours and with non-overlapping work hours of potential SLC i.

10 The implications of longer (or less coordinated) work hours by others Others’ work hours   p i   p i u(S i )   MU S  Given equilibrium condition, H*  to H**, and S*  to S**. Effect on A* ambiguous.

11 Further implications of the model Increase in full income: may increase total leisure (A+S) if normal good, but how solo leisure (A) and social leisure (S) each change is not clear Increase in own hourly wage: effect on work hours H depends on combination of income and substitution effects; effect on A and S also not determined (without extra assumptions) Overall, principal novelty = idea that when other persons increase their paid work hours, Pr(feasible and desirable leisure match) falls, which decreases own utility of non-work time. Also, … –for given total hours of labour supply by each person, greater mismatch between the timing of work hours of work will decrease Pr(social leisure time match), lowering utility of non-work time. –by reducing the utility of non-work time, both effects increase one’s own desired hours of paid work. Implication: the desired supply of labour of each person will be conditional on their expectations of the labour supply decisions of others (an externality hypothesis). Similarly, … Implication: own associative activity propensities depend on activities of others (SLC availability)  empirical work

12 Interdependencies between spouses in time use Spouse is a primary candidate for a Suitable Leisure Companion Conventional models of family emphasize interdependencies via household budget constraint … but … Spouses actually want to spend time together? Several theories suggest that the types of non-work activities by spouses is likely to be similar, but … Our point: conditional on preferences for type of activity and total work and leisure time, spouses derive utility from spending non-work time together. –Hence we expect to observe a correlation of the timing of working hours, for any given level of working hours  empirical work on spousal synchronisation of work times

13 Data: the BHPS British Household Panel Survey, waves 1–9 (1991–9). Has time use variables, and can use panel to control for individual effects, large and representative samples (cf. TUS) Sample of working couples –each spouse gave full interview, co-resident spouse, married or cohabiting, both aged 18– 59, both in paid employment (neither self- employed) –Unbalanced panel of c. 10,000 couple-years from c. 2,500 couples

14 Key variables Work hours: usual hours per week (including overtime) Hourly wage rate: usual gross pay  usual hours Scheduling of work hours: ‘At what time of the day do you usually work? Is it: 1 mornings only; 2 afternoons only; 3 during the day; 4 evenings only; 5 at night; 6 both lunch/evenings; 7 other times/day; 8 rotating shifts; 9 varies/no pattern; 10 other; or 11 daytimes & evenings’. –Spousal synchronisation of work hours if variable code is same –Prevalence of ‘unsocial hours’ in region ( pooled averages, codes 8&9 ) Associative activities (social leisure): whether reported activity in a (a) sports club, or (b) social group or working men’s club. (Most prevalent of 13 activities asked about.) –also used to derive measures of SLC availability: average activity rates by age group (18–30, 31–50, 51–59) and region [pooling data across waves] Reported ‘membership’ gave similar results.

15 Control variables in regressions Age Number of children aged less than 16 years, and whether youngest child aged less than 6 years Whether cohabiting rather than married Educational qualifications (five categories) Survey year (dummy variables) Labour demand structure and level: prevalence of unsocial hours, industry of main job (10 major SIC groups), and the unemployment rate in the local labour market (‘travel-to-work-area’); firm size (# employees)

16 Preliminary evidence on extra-household interdependence in associative activity Positive externality hypothesis: each person’s likelihood of participating in associational life depends on what others in their local area have chosen to do –one cannot join a club that does not exist for lack of membership; and the more members these organizations have, the more attractive they are to prospective members  expect that regions where a larger fraction of people participate in associational life will be regions where clubs and associations are more easily available, and more attractive to others Examine correlations between average rates by region across different age groups: –Figure 2: association between prevalence for middle-aged and youth of activity in (a) sports club and (b) social group or working men’s club Positive correlation between associative activity of one cohort and another in each chart, i.e consistent with our externality hypothesis.

17 Figure 2. Activity rates (regional averages) ( mean rate among 18–30 year-olds versus mean rate among 31–50 year olds) (a) Active in a sports club (b) Active in a social group or working men’s club

18 Synchronisation of usual daily working time In 51% of couples, spouses usually worked at the same time of the day Greater prevalence than would be expected from a random match of a husband’s and a wife’s work times (Pearson test of independence: p-value = ) Greater prevalence than would be expected due to the inherent constraints on daily time-use imposed by the regularity of office hours, school hours, and the hours of darkness, etc. –Create ‘pseudo-couples’ by matching otherwise-similar single men to married men, and otherwise-similar single women to married women (1:1 propensity score matching on age, education, work hours, kids): only 46% of pseudo-couples work at same time of day –Match every husband with every wife: synch. rate was 46% too!

19 More likely if husband hours not ‘unsocial’ NB good correspondence in ‘% in cat’ for real and pseudo-couples: good matching How does synchronisation vary with husband’s work time? Table 1 (part)

20 Synchronisation less likely, the more kids The more kids a couple has, the more likely spouses are to working at different times to save child care costs, or to give each parent quality time with kids: Table 1 (part)

21 Pr(spousal synchronisation of usual work hours) Random effects probit regressions Explanatory variables include (following previous literature): –wage rates of each spouse –work hours of each spouse –whether husband works during the day –regional prevalence of unsocial hours –control variables cited earlier Table 2: separate models for childless couples and parents

22

23 Pr(spousal synchronisation of usual work hours) the impacts of each spouse’s wage rate, holding each spouse’s work hours constant: two opposing influences (Hamermesh 2002): –Higher wages ceteris paribus act like an increase in full earnings, so expect the income effect to raise the work time synchronisation probability (the synchronisation-as-normal-good argument), versus –Husbands and wives who wish to play together may be willing to accept a wage penalty in order to do so. Or, in order to induce husbands and wives to work at different times, employers need to pay them more (compensating differential argument) Evidence of synchronisation-as-normal-good for wives but only for husbands with children (insig. for childless husbands) Strong positive effect of husband working during day Regional prevalence of unsocial hours not stat. signif.

24 Interdependencies in associative activities? 4-variate probit regression estimates of a couple’s activity propensities: Pr(husband active in social group or working men’s club, wife active in social group or working men’s club, husband active in sports club, wife active in sports club) Separate regressions by age group of husband: 18– 30, 31–50, 51–59 years (Tables 3, 4, 5) Key measure of extra-household SLC availability: mean regional activity rates for other age groups Spouse-as-SLC effects picked up by cross- equation correlations Control variables cited earlier also in regressions

25 Example

26 Interdependencies in associative activities? Main results from Tables 3–6 Some evidence of cross-cohort externalities in activity propensities (i.e. supportive of our core hypothesis). – E.g. young husbands were more likely to be active in a social club if there was a higher rate of activity among middle-aged husbands, and the middle-aged husbands were also more likely to be active if there was more activity among the young husbands or old ones –but no similar results for husband’s sports club activity. –Wives’ results differ: supportive evidence for the externality hypothesis concerns sports club activity (and only for wives with husbands aged 31–50) Regressions for single householders aged 31–50 also showed some partial support for our externality hypothesis (not shown) Cross-equation correlation structure consistent with core hypothesis (but identification issue! – assortative mating)

27 So what (if true)? The welfare effects of economy-wide increases in work hours [Background: 1980–2000, average work hours higher in USA than Europe, and difference grew] If externality exists, then when average working time rises, aggregate well-being falls by more than the cost of foregone wages Model suggests multiple equilibria in labour supply, some with lower aggregate utility. Maybe Americans work more hours partly because they’re more likely to have nobody to play with, and are worse off as result? Model draws an explicit link between rising work hours and decreasing social contacts. If ‘social capital’ related to latter (Putnam and others), then additional costs of high- work/low-social-contact equilibrium?