Imperfect Competition: A Game-Theoretic Approach

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Perfect Competition 12.
Advertisements

PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU
Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Copyright©2004 South-Western 17 Monopolistic Competition.
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition. Characteristics: Relatively Large Numbers Firms have a small market share No collusion (concerted action by firms to restrict.
Monopolistic competition Is Starbuck’s coffee really different from any other?
Ch. 11: Perfect Competition.  Explain how price and output are determined in perfect competition  Explain why firms sometimes shut down temporarily and.
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
Chapters 14 and 15 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Monopolistic Competition
Part 5 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Perfect Competition.
8 Perfect Competition  What is a perfectly competitive market?  What is marginal revenue? How is it related to total and average revenue?  How does.
Monopolistic Competition
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.  Selection of price and output  Shut down decision in short run.  Entry and exit behavior.  Predicting the effects of.
Perfect Competition 11-1 Chapter 11 Main Assumption Economists assume that the goal of firms is to maximize economic profit. Max P*Q – TC = Π = TR – TC.
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
Monopolistic Competition
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 Lecture 11 AND 12 PURE COMPETITION.
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION Wk Syllabus Outcomes Covered Describe, using examples, the assumed characteristics of a monopolistic competition Explain.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 8 Perfect Competition ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications, 4e HALL & LIEBERMAN, © 2008 Thomson South-Western.
Chapter 9 Pure Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Copyright McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002 Chapter 23: Pure Competition.
Persaingan Monopolistik versus Persaingan Sempurna.
Monopolistic Competition 1.Many firms (small market share each). 2.Acting independently (no collusion). 3.Products are differentiated. a. Actual differences.
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Monopolistic Competition
Copyright©2004 South-Western 17 Monopolistic Competition.
Monopolistic Competition
Copyright © 2004 South-Western CHAPTER 17 MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Appendix 13 Additional Models of Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition.
Lecture Notes. Firm Supply in Competitive Markets Market Environment: ways firms interact in making pricing and output decisions. Possibilities: (1) Perfect.
Imperfect Competition: A Game-Theoretic Approach
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION. Objectives  Define and identify monopolistic competition  Explain how output and price are determined in a monopolistically.
Competition Chapter 6 Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
The Production Decisions of Competitive Firms Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
Perfect Competition Chapter 9 ECO 2023 Fall 2007.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Monopolistic Competition 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 6. Competition Prof. Vera Adamchik.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Imperfectly Competitive Markets Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. What is a Pure Competition? Pure.
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 13A. After studying this chapter you will be able to Define and identify monopolistic competition Explain how output.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition Copyright © 2007 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 8 Perfect Competition ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications, 4e HALL & LIEBERMAN, © 2008 Thomson South-Western.
Monopolistic Competition. Monopolistic Competition is based upon a number of assumptions Many buyers and many sellers No barriers to entry or exit Differentiated.
Chapters (8) Perfect Competition (8) Monopoly (8).
UBEA 1013: ECONOMICS 1 CHAPTER 5: MARKET STRUCTURE: PERFECT COMPETITION 5.1 Characteristic 5.2 Short-run Decision: Profit Maximization 5.3 Short-run Decision:
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Monopolistic Competition Economics 101. Definition  Monopolistic Competition  Many firms selling products that are similar but not identical.  Markets.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Mods Monopolistic Competition & Advertising.
Copyright McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002 Pure Competition 23 C H A P T E R.
Pure (perfect) Competition Please listen to the audio as you work through the slides.
Chapter 8 Perfect Competition ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications, 4e HALL & LIEBERMAN, © 2008 Thomson South-Western.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Monopolistic Competition Characteristics: –Many sellers –Product differentiation –Free entry and exit –In the long run,
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
Imperfect Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition and Advertising
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
Introduction to Monopolistic Competition
Chapter 7: Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition & Price Discrimination
Presentation transcript:

Imperfect Competition: A Game-Theoretic Approach Chapter 13 Imperfect Competition: A Game-Theoretic Approach Monopolistic Competition 13-1

The Chamberlin Model Assumption: a clearly defined “industry group,” which consists of a large number of producers of products that are close, but imperfect substitutes for one another. Two implications: Because the products are viewed as close substitutes, each firm will confront a downward-sloping demand schedule. Each firm will act as if its own price and quantity decisions have no effect on the behavior of other firms in the industry. That is, its competitors do not respond to its pricing and output decisions. But symmetry makes sense for other firms to respond to this behavior. Thus, the firm faces 2 demand curves: (a) when the firm alone changes price, and (b) when prices change in unison. Since the goods are perceived as close substitutes, each firm perceives the demand curve facing it as highly elastic. 13-2

The Chamberlin Model (a) The firm alone changes the price (dd) and (b) when all firms change prices (DD) Gain when ALL firms change prices along DD Advantage of being 1st mover alone along the dd curve Figure 13.11: The Monopolistic Competitor’s Two Demand Curves Figure 13.12: Short-Run Equilibrium for the Chamberlinian Firm At the initial price, P’, each firm sells Q’. If the firm lowers P to P”, it sells Q”’ along dd curve. BUT if ALL prices change, then each firm sells only Q” along DD curve Figure 13.12: In the SR, assume the firm has dd curve and the equilibrium is Q* at P* with ATCQ*. Since P* > ATCQ*. , it follows that the green rectangle is short-term profits. As in PC, profits invites entry into the industry (free entry & exit) 13-3

Figure 13.13: Long-Run Equilibrium in the Chamberlin Model Entry leads to a leftward shift of the demand curve, i.e. after entry, each firm contributes proportionately less to industry output. In the LR, entry drives profits to zero (just as in PC). Recall: PC = Perfect Competition E PPC E’ QPC 13-4

Perfect Competition Versus Chamberlinian Monopolistic Competition Competition meets the test of allocative efficiency(P=MC), while monopolistic competition does not (P>MC). Monopolistic competition is less efficient than perfect competition because in the former case firms do not produce at the minimum points of their long-run average cost (LAC) curves (E > E’) In terms of long-run profitability the equilibrium positions of both the perfect competitor and the Chamberlinian monopolistic competitor are precisely the same (P = ATC in both) 13-5

Criticisms of the Chamberlin Model Arbitrary definition of an “industry group.” Chamberlin thought of group of products that are different from each other and providing variety (Stigler) It complicates PC without changing its fundamental results (Friedman) Too closely resembles the PC especially its assumption that any firm can attract any buyers in an industry. These criticisms have lead to the development of models that yield different results than the Chamberlin model.

EXAMPLE Suppose each of the 20 firms in monopolistic competition faces a dd curve of the form: P = 10 – 0.001Q. What is each firm’s dd curve following the entry of 5 firms? Before Entry: MR = 10 –0. 002Q and set = 0 and solve for Q = 5,000. Divide 5000 by 20 firms to get a firm’s share: 5000/20 = 250. Thus, in % terms, each firm has 250/5000 = 1/20 = 5%. P=10, and Q = 10,000 After entry: Divide 5000 by 25 = 200 and in % terms, the share is 200/5000 =1/25 = 4%. Thus, at each price, quantity demanded will be 20% less, i.e. P = 10 – 0.00125Q so that P =10 but Q = 8,000 (where 0.000125 = 1/8000) P=10 8,000 10,000

Criticisms of the Chamberlin Model Arbitrary definition of an “industry group.” Chamberlin thought of group of products that are different from each other and providing variety (Stigler) It complicates PC without changing its fundamental results (Friedman) Too closely resembles the PC especially its assumption that any firm can attract any buyers in an industry. These criticisms have lead to the development of models that yield different results than the Chamberlin model.

Figure 13.14: An Industry in Which Location is the Important Differentiating Feature The Optimal Number of Locations The number of outlets that emerges from the independent actions of profit-seeking firms will in general be related to the optimal number of outlets in the following simple way  4 equally space outlets (green); circumference = 1mile Distance as reducing substitutability Any environmental change that leads to a change in the optimal number of outlets (here, any change in population density, transportation cost, or fixed cost) will lead to a change in the same direction in the equilibrium number of outlets. 13-9

Figure 13.16: The Optimal Number of Outlets Optimal N* = where the slopes of the 2 curves are equal # CMtrans – total transportation costs ; declines with the number of outlets (restaurants in this case)(N) # CMMeals – total cost of meals served ; increases with the number of outlets N) #N* - optimal number of restaurants, i.e. the one that minimizes the sum of these costs. At t (transportation costs ) rises, so do N as people economize on transportation by going to nearer restaurants. Similarly, if L (population) rises, high density in the area increases N (see Natomas). If restaurant start-up costs (F) increase, N decreases (e.g. zoning costs) 13-10

Figure 13.17: A Spatial Interpretation of Airline Scheduling Preference for a 5 PM flight can be easily accommodated by the closet substitute – flight at 6P.M. in the airline ‘product space.’ 5 P.M. Why not have a flight leaving every 5 minutes, so that no one would be forced to travel at an inconvenient time? The larger an aircraft is, the lower its average cost per seat is. If people want frequent flights, airlines are forced to use smaller planes and charge higher fares (commuter airlines) 13-11

Figure 13.18: Distributing the Cost of Variety Desire for variety increases with income; those with a preference for a wide variety have the income to back-up their demands, i.e. automobile market. Buyers who care more about special features will buy the higher priced Cadillac while the opposite is true of those who might care but have low incomes Note that by charging more for Cadillac's, the producer is able to recoup the cost of “variety” even if the MC of both types are hardly different. Note that the cost of ‘variety’ is not evenly distributed across consumers 13-12

Consumer Preferences And Advertising Because products are differentiated, producers can often shift their demand curves outward significantly by advertising. The revised sequence -- the corporation decides which products are cheapest and most convenient to produce, and then uses advertising and other promotional devices to create demand for them. 13-13