Indifference Curves and Individual and Social Production Possibilities

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
Advertisements

Chapter 6A Practice Quiz Indifference Curve Analysis
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Budget Today or Tomorrow
Indifference Curves and
WHY DOES THE DEMAND CURVE SLOPE DOWNWARD?
Consumer Behavior Esa Unggul University Budget Constraints Preferences do not explain all of consumer behavior. Budget constraints also limit an.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Calculate and graph a budget line that shows the.
Chapter Thirty Production. Exchange Economies (revisited) u No production, only endowments, so no description of how resources are converted to consumables.
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
12 Consumer Choice and Demand
© 2013 Pearson. How much would you pay for a song?
Budget Constraint –Budget constraints limit an individual’s ability to consume in light of the prices they must pay for various goods and services. The.
11 PART 4 Consumer Choice and Demand A CLOSER LOOK AT DECISION MAKERS
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior.
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Changes in Income An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel manner An increase in income will cause the budget constraint.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
Introduction to Economics
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
1 Indifference Curve and Consumer Choice. 2 Overview Illustrated using example of choices on movies and concerts Assumptions of preference –______________________.
Consumer Preferences, Utility Functions and Budget Lines Overheads.
CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer. 2 What you will learn in this chapter: How consumers choose to spend their income on goods and services Why consumers.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Individual Behavior MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy David J. Bryce.
Terrel Gallaway: Public Finance 1 Excess Burden u The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics says that, under ideal conditions, the behavior of.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
1 Individual Choice Principles of Microeconomics Professor Dalton ECON 202 – Fall 2013.
Consumer behaviorslide 1 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Preferences. The conflict between opportunities and desires. Utility maximizing behavior.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand Chapter 8.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
Lecture 5. How to find utility maximizing bundle/ optimal bundle A consumer if better off if he can reach to a higher indifference curve. Due to the limited.
The Theory of Individual Behavior. Overview I. Consumer Behavior n Indifference Curve Analysis n Consumer Preference Ordering II. Constraints n The Budget.
1 Individual and Social Production Possibilities and Indifference Curves International Economics Professor Dalton ECON 317 – Spring 2012.
Lecture 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 1 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Consumer behaviour: Ordinal approach Now, we go to the ordinal approach. Ordinalist cares only about ranking. It doesn’t matter if we say U(A) = 20, U(B)
1 Quick Review Utility Maximization Econ Fall 2007.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
Theory of Consumer Behaviour
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE
CHAPTER 31 PRODUCTION. The Robinson Crusoe Economy One consumer and one firm; The consumer owns the firm; Preference: over leisure and coconuts; Technology:
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 10-1 CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all rights.
CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer.
Chapter 6 Supply of Labor to the Economy: The Decision to Work.
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Utility- is the satisfaction you receive from consuming a good or service Total utility is the number of units of utility that a consumer gains from consuming.
Chapter Five The Demand Curve and the Behavior of Consumers.
Introduction to Neoclassical Trade Theory: Tools to Be Employed Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 32 Production.
Chapter 32 Production. Exchange Economies (revisited) No production, only endowments, so no description of how resources are converted to consumables.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Possibilities, Preferences and Choice ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
BUS 525: Managerial Economics Lecture 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior.
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
1 Indifference Curve Analysis Intermediate Microeconomics Professor Dalton ECON 303 – Fall 2008.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
1 Production. 2 Exchange Economies (revisited) No production, only endowments, so no description of how resources are converted to consumables. General.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
Presentation transcript:

Indifference Curves and Individual and Social Production Possibilities International Economics Professor Dalton ECON 317 – Fall 2014

Indifference Curves Characteristics 1. Fixed preferences Y/time Characteristics 1. Fixed preferences 2. Negatively-sloped 3. Higher indifference curve represents greater utility 4. Convex 5. Non-intersecting 6. Slope = Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRSxy) U3 U2 U1 X/time

Indifference Curves A B Y/time The Marginal Rate of Substitution represents a trade-off ratio; the marginal benefit from a unit of one good in terms of another. A 11 If the individual is at point A, an additional unit of X is worth 2Y. 9 B 3.2 U2 If the individual is at B, an additional X is worth 0.2 Y. 3 3 4 11 12 X/time

Budget Constraint A budget constraint is negatively-sloped, reflecting the notion of opportunity cost - one must give up one good to get more of another. The slope of a budget constraint measures the opportunity cost of one additional unit of a good in terms of the foregone units of the other good.

Budget Constraint In consumer choice, the budget constraint usually consists of an income constraint reflecting relative prices of the two goods. The budget constraint can also consist of a PPF. In either case, the slope of a budget constraint measures the opportunity cost of one additional unit of a good in terms of the foregone units of the other good.

Budget Constraint What is the slope of the budget constraint? Slope equals rise over run. For an income constraint, slope equals I/Py divided by I/Px. (where I is income and Pj is the price of good j) I/Py/I/Px = Px/Py Y/time The slope of the budget constraint equals the price ratio Px/Py I Py A C I Px X/time

Budget Constraint The slope of the budget constraint equals MRTx,y What is the slope of the individual production possibility frontier? Slope equals rise over run. For an PPF, slope equals Y divided by X, and is the Marginal Rate of Transformation, MRTx,y. Y/time The slope of the budget constraint equals MRTx,y A C Y X X/time

Individual Production Possibilities Y/time An individual’s production possibilities frontier shows the quantities of goods, X and Y, that can be produced within a given time period while efficiently using the resources at hand. 30 X/time 15

Individual Production Possibilities Y/time The slope equals ΔY/ΔX. Y = MPLY (L) and X =MPLX (L), so ΔY/ΔX = MPLY (L)/MPLX (L), or simply MPLY/MPLX. Begin with simple case of constant productivity. Suppose that L = 10, and MPLY = 3 and MPLX = 1.5. 30 At maximum, individual can produce Y = (10)(3) = 30 units of Y and X = (10)(1.5) = 15 units of X. X/time 15

Individual to Social Production Possibilities Y/time Slope is called the marginal rate of transformation between X and Y, abbreviated MRTx,y, and it representahow much it costs in Y to produce an X 30 Slope is 30/15 = 2 The marginal cost of X = 2Y The marginal cost of Y = 1/2 X X/time 15

It depends upon what is meant by “best”! Three Individual PPFs Y Y Y 180 Joe Sam Bill 100 30 30 X 150 X 120 X Which individual is the best producer of X? Which individual is the best producer of Y? It depends upon what is meant by “best”!

Comparative and Absolute Advantage A person is said to have an absolute advantage in producing a good if he can produce more of the good than can another. A person is said to have a comparative advantage in producing a good if he can produce the good at a lower cost than another.

Three Individual PPFs Absolute Advantage Y Y Y 180 Joe Sam Bill 100 30 30 X 150 X 120 X Absolute Advantage: Good X Sam (150) Bill (120) Joe (30) Absolute Advantage: Good Y Bill (180) Sam (100) Joe (30)

Three Individual PPFs Comparative Advantage Y Y Y 180 Joe Sam Bill 100 30 30 X 150 X 120 X Comparative Advantage: Good X Sam: 2/3 Y Joe: 1 Y Bill: 3/2 Y Comparative Advantage: Good Y Bill: 2/3 X Joe: 1 X Sam: 3/2 X

Building the Social PPF Y Y Y 180 Comparative Advantage: Good X Sam: 2/3 Y Joe: 1 Y Bill: 3/2 Y Bill Joe 30 310 30 X X 120 Y Sam 100 150 X 300 X

Building the Social PPF The Social PPF is the “summation” of all the individual agents’ PPFs in the economy, constructed by applying the principle of comparative advantage.

Slope is flat at A. Low opportunity cost of X. Many Person Social PPF Slope is flat at A. Low opportunity cost of X. Y/time A Slope is steep at B. High opportunity cost of X. B X/time

Choice: Combining Indifference Curves with Production Possibilities Y/time Here, MRSx,y > Px/Py (or MRTx,y). The individual can buy an additional X for less than the additional unit is valued. MC MB Here, MRSx,y < Px/Py (or MRTx,y). The individual would have to pay more than the additional unit of X is valued. U3 U2 U1 1 2 X/time

Choice When the MRSx,y > Px/Py Y/time When the MRSx,y > Px/Py (or MRSx,y > MRTx,y) , the individual can make himself better off by selling a unit of Y to purchase additional units of X, since a unit of X is valued more highly than a unit of Y at the going prices. So long as this remains true, the individual continues to move “down” his budget constraint. 1Y U3 U2 U1 1 3 X/time

He will have maximized his utility! Choice Y/time When MRSx,y = Px/Py (or MRSx,y = MRTx,y), the individual will have reached a point where he can make himself no better off by a rearrangement of resources in X and Y consumption. Y* U3 U2 U1 He will have maximized his utility! X* X/time

Changes in the Budget Constraint Y/time Starting from an original budget constraint … Suppose that the price of X falls… The consumer can now buy more X if all income is spent on X… But can buy no more Y if all income is spent on Y… X/time The budget constraint rotates outward “around” the original Y-intercept

Changes in the Budget Constraint Y/time Starting from an original budget constraint … Suppose that the price of X increases… The consumer can now buy less X if all income is spent on X… But can buy no more Y if all income is spent on Y… X/time The budget constraint rotates inward “around” the original Y-intercept

Changes in the Budget Constraint Y/time Starting from an original budget constraint … Suppose that the price of Y falls… The consumer can now buy more Y if all income is spent on Y… But can buy no more X if all income is spent on X… X/time The budget constraint rotates outward “around” the original X-intercept

Changes in the Budget Constraint Y/time Starting from an original budget constraint … Suppose that the price of Y increases… The consumer can now buy less Y if all income is spent on Y… But can buy no more X if all income is spent on X… X/time The budget constraint rotates inward “around” the original X-intercept

Changes in the Budget Constraint Y/time Starting from an original budget constraint … Suppose that money income I increases… The consumer can now buy more Y if all income is spent on Y… and can buy more X if all income is spent on X… X/time The budget constraint shifts outward. Does the slope change? NO.

Changes in the Budget Constraint Y/time Starting from an original budget constraint … Suppose that money income I decreases… The consumer can now buy less Y if all income is spent on Y… and can buy less X if all income is spent on X… X/time The budget constraint shifts inward. Does the slope change? NO.

Changes in Indifference Curves Y/time Start from an original set of Indifference Curves (only one of which is shown). If the individual is at point A, an additional unit of X is worth 2Y. A 11 9 Suppose that the individual’s preferences change so that X is now valued more highly (he prefers X relatively more)… 6 U2 Now the individual will value an additional unit of X at more than 2Y, say 5Y… 3 4 X/time The set of indifference curves will become steeper…

Changes in Indifference Curves Y/time Start from an original set of Indifference Curves (only one of which is shown). If the individual is at point A, an additional unit of X is worth 2Y. A 11 10 Suppose that the individual’s preferences change so that Y is now valued more highly (he prefers X relatively less)… U2 Now the individual will value an additional unit of X at less than 2Y, say 1Y… 3 4 11 12 X/time The set of indifference curves will become flatter…

Changes in Behavior: Price Y/time Beginning from equilibrium, suppose that Px falls. The budget constraint rotates outward around the Y-intercept… Y** Y* U3 U2 The consumer chooses a new X, Y combination: X**, Y** U1 X* X** X/time

Changes in Behavior: Price Y/time Beginning from equilibrium, suppose that Px rises. The budget constraint rotates outward around the Y-intercept… Y’ Y* U3 U2 The consumer chooses a new X, Y combination: X’, Y’ U1 X’ X* X/time

Changes in Behavior: Income Y/time Beginning from equilibrium, suppose that Income rises. The budget constraint shifts outward and the slope doesn’t change (why?) Y** Y* U3 U2 U1 The consumer chooses a new X, Y combination: X**, Y** X* X** X/time

Changes in Behavior: Income Y/time As this graph what kind of goods are X and Y? Both are normal goods. Y** Y* U3 U2 U1 X* X** X/time

Changes in Behavior: Income Y/time Suppose, that instead, money income had fallen. Again that means a new equilibrium, and a new equilibrium combination of X’ and Y’. Y* U3 Y’ U2 U1 X’ X* X/time

Changes in Behavior: Preferences Y/time Start from an original equilibrium, A. Suppose preferences become more favorable to X…the IC steepen. A Y* B Y** The individual now moves to a bundle favoring more X and Less Y, at B. X* X** X/time

Social Indifference Curves? Can we sum up the preferences of individuals into a social indifference curve? We could if we could measure the intensity of preferences independent of income levels, or measure utility directly. But we can’t. Further, Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem shows that there exists no rule that allows us to combine preferences without giving some one person in society totalitarian power over the resulting choice.

TANSTAASIC There ain’t no such thing as a Social Indifference Curve…(sometimes called a Social Welfare Function). But BEWARE, textbooks and journal articles often present graphs that pretend that we can aggregate individual preferences into a Social Preference Ordering – a Social Indifference Curve.

TANSTAASIC For a two good world, we can employ the fiction that the indifference curve represents the preferences of the marginal or representative individual in society. When we move to more than two goods, however, this fiction becomes untenable.

TANSTAASIC Why use graphs that show Country PPFs and Country ICs? (that violate TANSTAASIC!) As a short-hand for the more complicated process of actual price formation…that’s all. Don’t commit the fallacy of misplaced concreteness.