Chapter 2: Gains from Trade Keith Head Sauder School of Business.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 2: Gains from Trade Keith Head Sauder School of Business.
Advertisements

Perfect Competition 12.
Correcting Market Distortions: Shadow Prices, Shadow Wages and Discount Rates Chapter 6.
Chapter 7 (7.1 – 7.4) Firm’s costs of production: Accounting costs: actual dollars spent on labor, rental price of bldg, etc. Economic costs: includes.
Chapter 7 The Cost of Production. Chapter 7Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter? Cost in the Short Run Cost in the Long Run.
Europe and the Single Market Originally the EU was envisaged as a market where goods, services, people and money could move freely. This would be done.
International Trade and Comparative Advantage
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Airlines and automobile producers are facing tough times: Prices are being slashed to drive sales and profits are turning.
The Theory and Estimation of Production
Part 5 The Theory of Production and Cost
Gains from Trade John Ries Sauder School of Business, University of British Columbia.
A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1: Brainstorming
The Determination of Costs Howard Davies. Objectives n To examine the relationship between inputs and outputs n To identify the most important determinants.
Ch. 21: Production and Costs Del Mar College John Daly ©2003 South-Western Publishing, A Division of Thomson Learning.
Supply & Costs of Production
CHAPTER 5 SUPPLY.
Cost Analysis and Estimation
COSTS AND PRODUCTIVITY
The Costs of Production 1 22 C H A P T E R Costs exist because resources Are scarce Productive Have alternative uses Use of a resource in a specific.
Why does production have a cost? because.... Scarcity Inputs are scarce. They have opportunity costs.
Cost – The Root of Supply Total Cost Average Cost Marginal Cost Fixed Cost Variable Cost Long Run Average Costs Economies of Scale.
Economies of Scale Is Bigger Really Better?. Economies of Scale Economies of scale refers to the phenomena of decreased per unit cost as the number of.
KEY WORDS: Economy of Scale ; cost per unit ; internal ; external Economies of Scale  This section is split into 4 sections ;  1. Internal economy of.
Chapter 5 The Firm: Production and Cost. Copyright © 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.5-2 Learning Objectives List the advantages and.
Principles of Microeconomics : Ch.13 First Canadian Edition Supply The Costs of Production The Law of Supply: Firms are willing to produce and sell a greater.
Classical Economics & Relative Prices. Classical Economics Classical economics relies on three main assumptions: Classical economics relies on three main.
Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter?
The Costs of Production Ratna K. Shrestha
The Costs of Production
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2006 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. The Costs of Production Chapter 6.
By: Christopher Mazzei. Viewpoints The owner of a company wants to keep costs down. An employee of the company wants a high wage or salary. There is always.
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Total Revenue, Total Cost, Profit
The Costs of Production
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Chapter 9 Supply Under Perfect Competition Introduction to Economics (Combined Version) 5th Edition.
1 of 37 PART II The Market System: Choices Made by Households and Firms © 2012 Pearson Education CHAPTER OUTLINE 9 Long-Run Costs and Output Decisions.
Production and Efficiency. Content Specialisation Division of labour Exchange Production and productivity Economies of Scale Economic Efficiency.
4.2 Organisation of Production
The Costs of Production Chapter 6. In This Chapter… 6.1. The Production Process 6.2. How Much to Produce? 6.3. The Right Size: Large or Small?
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
Chapter 25 Short-Term Business Decisions
Chapter 7 The Cost of Production. Chapter 7Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter? Cost in the Short Run Cost in the Long Run.
1 Long-Run Costs and Output Decisions Chapter 9. 2 LONG-RUN COSTS AND OUTPUT DECISIONS We begin our discussion of the long run by looking at firms in.
Chapter 7 The Cost of Production. Chapter 7Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter? Cost in the Short Run Cost in the Long Run.
Principles of Microeconomics : Ch.13 Second Canadian Edition Chapter 13 The Costs of Production © 2002 by Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Limited.
CHAPTER 5 COST OF PRODUCTION. PART 1: SHORT RUN PRODUCTION COST Chapter Summary Types of production cost in short run Apply the short run production cost.
MBMC Perfectly Competitive Supply: The Cost Side of The Market Part II.
GLOBAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT ENVIRONMENT INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY [R/H, Ch.6, ] [Head, pp.33-44] Various economic theories try to explain observed.
CHAPTER 18 EXTENSIONS TO SUPPLY AND DEMAND By Lauren O’Brien, Peter Cervantes, Erik Borders.
Production Economics Chapter 7
Chapter Seventeen The Gains from International Trade.
The Costs of Production M icroeonomics P R I N C I P L E S O F N. Gregory Mankiw
21-1 The Costs of Production  Before anyone can consume to satisfy wants and needs, goods and services must be produced.  Producers are profit-seeking,
Study Unit 7 The cost of production. Outcomes Different concepts of costs in economics Cost in the short run Cost in the long run Short run cost vs. long.
Long-Run Costs and Economies of Scale Module 56. Behind the Supply Curve.
Economies of Scale Introduction and appropriation issues.
MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS COST ANALYSIS. In this chapter, look for answers to production and cost questions: What is a production function? What is marginal.
N. G R E G O R Y M A N K I W Premium PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich 2008 update © 2008 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved.
Costs/Productivity - Part 4 (Pp of textbook) M. Padula AIS Theory of the Firm Part I.
0 Chapter 13. You run General Motors.  List 3 different costs you have.  List 3 different business decisions that are affected by your costs. 1 A C.
Production and Cost in the Firm
Perfectly Competitive Supply: The Cost Side of The Market
The Costs of Production
Business Economics (ECO 341) Lecture 6
Trading and Factory Towns
Unit 4: Costs of Production
economics CHAPTER 4 : THEORY OF PRODUCTION and cost
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 2: Gains from Trade Keith Head Sauder School of Business

Objectives of this chapter Illustrate the gains from trade based on exploiting comparative advantage Show how productivity, wages, competitive advantage, and exchange rates relate to each other. Illustrate the gains from trade based on exploiting plant-level scale economies.

Your assignment: Decide the number of workers in each of two factories (Korea & Thailand) to allocate to each of two activities (molding soles & stitching uppers). Maximize corporate shoe output

Shoe terms Sole Upper

Assumptions 450 workers in Thai factory 300 workers in Korean factory In the short run, you cannot add or subtract workers, or move them between plants. One sole and one upper needed for each finished shoe. Transport costs are negligible

Productivity Matrix Factory: Activity: UppersSoles Korea 1545 Thailand 1020

Compute total shoe output for Plan A: (self-sufficient factories): Each country combines workers to produce completed shoes. There is no trade. Plan B: –Thailand produces only uppers, –Korea produces soles and uppers. Plan C: –Korea produces only uppers, –Thailand produces soles and uppers.

Plan A (self-sufficient factories): Thailand: U=S  10Lu = 20(450-Lu) Lu= 300, Ls = 150, output = 3000 Korea: U=S  15Lu = 45(300-Lu) Lu= 225 Ls = 75, output = 3375 Combined output = 6375 shoes 6375/750 = 8.5 shoes per worker

Plan B: Thailand specializes in uppers Thailand: Lu =450  4500 uppers Korea: U=S  Lu =45(300-Lu) Lu = 150  2250 U, Ls =150  6750S Combined output: 6750 shoes – 4500 shoes stitched in Thailand using soles imported from Korea –PLUS 2250 finished shoes made in Korea Productivity: 9 shoes per worker

Plan C: Korea specializes in Uppers Korea: Lu = 300  4500 uppers Thailand: U=S  Lu=20(450-Lu) Lu = 150  1500 U, Ls=300  6000 S Combined output: 6000 shoes – 4500 shoes stitched in Korea using soles imported from Thailand –PLUS 1500 finished shoes made in Thailand Productivity: 6000/750 = 8 shoes/worker

Plan B increases shoe output by 6% Firm-level productivity rises 8.5 to 9 shoes per day Output growth: ( )/6375 =.06 No new machinery, no new skills, no extra effort. Trade is like a new technology!

Specialization is not enough Plan C, involves specialization but it lowers output by 6% relative to Plan A. Specialization based on comparative advantage yields gains from trade. Comparative advantage = low opportunity costs. CA gains = matching process

Opportunity cost calculations Opportunity cost of uppers in foregone soles –Thailand: 20 S/ 10 U = 2 S/U –Korea: 45S/15U = 3 S/U Opportunity cost of soles in foregone uppers –Thailand: 10 U/ 20 S = 0.5 U/S –Korea: 15U/45S = 0.33 U/S Korea has lower opportunity cost of seouls!

Beyond “Guess &Check”: general method Determine comparative advantage via opportunity cost calculation (T->U, K->S) Check if complete specialization is possible: compare [prody in CA task] X [factory size] for each factory –T: 10 X 450=4500, K: 45 X 300 = –So, Thai factory is “too small” (it needs 1350 or more) If no, then the “too small” factory fully specializes in its CA task but the “too big” factory will partially specialize –Supply from too small + non-CA supply from too big = CA supply from too big –10 X X L = 45 (300-L)

Long run decisions The level of employment is only fixed in each plant in the short run. When employment is a decision variable, not a sunk cost, then wages and productivity matter.

Calculate the critical wages If wages were equal, Korea’s factory would be the low cost source for both uppers and soles. (Why? AA) How low would Thai wages have to be justify operating the plant? (doing what?) How low would the wage in Thailand have to be to justify shutting the Korean plant? Draw the Korean relative wage line.

Competitive advantage A factory has a competitive advantage in a task when it can provide an equivalent product at a lower monetary cost than alternatives. Competitive advantage here corresponds to lower unit labour costs. Unit labour costs are given by wages divided by productivity.

Unit Labour Costs (in baht/unit) FactoryFactory Activity: UppersSoles Korea eW K /15e W K /45 Thailand W T /10W T /20 W K = wages in Korea (won/worker) W T = wages in Thailand (baht/worker) e = exchange rate (baht/won)

Thai plant gains competitive advantage in uppers when Korea pays 50% more than the Thai wage  e W K /15 > W T /10  eW K /W T > 1.5 in soles when Korea pays 2.25 times the Thai wage  e W K /45 > W T /20  eW K /W T > 2.25

Competitive Advantage & Equilibrium Exchange Rates Suppose that unions or government fix the local currency values of wages at W K = 100 Won/day and W T = 200 Baht/day. What values of e (in Baht/Won) would be consistent with equilibrium (green zone)? How would the e range change if Thai productivity doubled in all activities?

Exchange rate zones Recall the green zone for the relative wage: 1.5 <eWk/Wt <2.25 Now set Wk/Wt =100/200 =1/2, 1.5 <e (1/2) <2.25 To simplify, just multiply everywhere by 2, we get 3<e<4.5. If productivity in Thailand doubles, then we need to divide 1.5 and 2.25 by two, so the new range is.75<eWk/Wt< Substitute in Wk/Wt= 100/200 =1/2 as before and multiply by 2 across the board, to get 1.5<e<2.25 Baht/Won must decline…won depreciates, baht appreciates

Equilibrium relative wages: eW K /W T Suppose wages are so high in Korea that unit labour costs are higher there than in Thailand for both goods, e W K / W T >2.25. –No firms would want to employ Korean workers and, hence, there would be no Korean products. Wages is Korea would fall and the won would depreciate (e=baht/won would fall). –Eventually, Korea would be low cost (have a competitive advantage) in one good (the comparative advantage good.)

Lessons from the Shoe Story Making sense of the Asian exchange rate crisis. Average levels of productivity in the traded goods sector determine wages. –Low wage countries are also low- productivity –Rising productivity leads to appreciation Low wage countries do not “steal” all industries—only the ones where their relative wage advantage outweighs their productivity disadvantage.

Shoe Story II: Returns to Scale Comparative advantage is not the only way to obtain gains from trade. Plant-level economies of scale (PLEoS) are important in many industries. To illustrate the gains from exploiting PLEoS through trade, we revise the story to exclude comparative advantage and absolute advantage.

New Productivity Matrix Factory: Activity: UppersSoles Korea 10 Thailand 10

Indivisible Overhead Factory workers are supported by services of non-production employees, also known as “overhead” –Accounting –Logistics and input procurement –Machinery maintenance Some minimum number of overhead workers are required for any positive level of production.

New example 300 workers at each factory Let overhead be 30 workers per “product” (soles or uppers) per plant. A factory that produces both products (that is, a factory that is not fully specialized) has overhead of 30+30= 60, leaving =240 workers for production. A factory that specializes has =270 workers for production.

Calculate gains from specialization and trade Calculate shoe output with self- sufficient factories (plan A) Calculate shoe output with Korea specializing in soles and Thailand in uppers (plan B) What is the increase in productivity?

Plan A vs Plan B revisited Plan A (self-sufficiency): –Sole output in each factory: (240/2)*10 = 1200 –Upper output in each factory: (240/2)*10 = 1200 –Combined output = =2400 shoes

Revisiting Plan B Plan B (full specialization, K  S,T  U): –Sole output in Korea: 270*10 = 2700 –Upper output in Thailand: 270*10 =2700 –Combined output = 2700 shoes (11% gain!)

PLEoS gains are different from CA gains Plan C (full specialization K  U and T  S) is just as good (2700 shoes) as plan B No such thing as specializing in the “wrong” thing in this case. The key for PLEoS is to avoid duplicative overhead, rather than to “match” products with skills (as in the CA case)

PLEoS vs CA (cont’d) In the long run, only one plant stays open (whichever has lower ULC) Under PLEoS, increases in total production increase productivity, whether or not factories are specialized. Under CA, changing scale of plants doesn’t help unless you change the mix of activities done in each. Under CA, observe larger plant to be less productive.

Geometric PLEoS Surface to volume ratios of three dimensional objects are a source of PLEoS. –The formula for the surface to volume ratio of a vat is decreasing in the volume (see EMS, p.35). Thus, as the vat size increases, the per volume cost of the material to make the vat (steel) is falling Geometric PLEoS apply to vats, tanks, furnaces, and even buildings

Two-way trade and scale economies Recall, Canada is both a big exporter and a big importer of cars, machinery, and industrial equipment This can be explained by companies producing product varieties and concentrating individual varieties in single factories

Before Canada-US Autopact (1965) Minivans Sedans Local sales Minivans Local sales Sedans Canada US

After Canada-US Autopact (1965) Minivans Sedans Local sales Canada US Canadian exports Canadian imports

Benefits Plant-level fixed costs are eliminated by concentrating individual varieties in single factories Would a cost-minimizing firm prefer to locate both factories in the United States? –Yes, transport costs are minimized by locating in the large market.

Gains from Trade Summary When relative productivities of two tasks (uppers, soles) differ across locations, there are CA gains. When there is indivisible overhead (or other PLEoS), concentrating activities in one location helps. Next question: what is the ultimate source of opportunity costs diffs?