12 | Environmental Protection and Negative Externalities The Economics of Pollution Command-and-Control Regulation Market-Oriented Environmental Tools.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
4 THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR. Copyright©2004 South-Western 10 Externalities.
Advertisements

1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
Ch. 30: Market Failure Externalities, Public Goods, and Asymmetric Information Del Mar College John Daly ©2003 South-Western Publishing, A Division of.
In chapter 10, we look for the answers to these questions:
SMART Classes First Year Chapter (2) The Modern Mixed Economy
10 Externalities.
1 Chapter 3 Externalities and Public Policy. 2 Externalities Externalities are costs or benefits of market transactions not reflected in prices. Negative.
Externalities.
SUNK COSTS & THE EXTERNALITIES 1. Index 1. Sunk costs Sunk costs 2. Shubik’s Theory Shubik’s Theory 3. Ernest Dupuis III Ernest Dupuis III 4. Sunk costs.
Externalities © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted.
4 THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR. Copyright©2004 South-Western 10 Externalities.
1 of 30 Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall · Economics · R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 3e. Chapter 5: Externalities,
Externalities Chapter 10 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
© 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 5 Externalities,
Chapter 17 Externalities and the Environment © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
When the market works as it should…
An externality arises when a person engages in an activity that influences the well-being of one or more bystanders with the person engaging in the.
POST GRADUATE DIPLOMA IN BUSINESS MANAGEMENT November 2013 Lesson 1.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Environmental Economics.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Externalities Chapter 10 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 10 Externalities
Principles of Micro Chapter 10: Externalities by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Market Efficiency - Market Failures The “invisible hand” leads self-interested.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 10 Externalities. Copyright © 2004 South-Western EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY An externality refers to the uncompensated.
How can we limit climate change?
Chapter 10 notes Externalities.
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
Externalities ECO 230 J.F. O’Connor. Topics Nature of externalities Why do externalities cause market failure Private solutions to an externality problem.
A lesson from chapter 7: Competitive markets are “efficient” -- they lead to maximum total surplus. The price rationing mechanism allocates output to.....
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Harcourt Brace & Company Chapter 10 Externalities (Lecture by D. Boldt on 10/18/01 in Econ
Review for Exam 1 Chapters 1 Through 5. Production Possibilities Frontiers and Opportunity Costs Learning Objective 2.1 Production possibilities frontier.
Principles of Microeconomics : Ch.10 Second Canadian Edition Externalities Chapter 10 © 2002 by Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Limited.
Chapter 10 Externalities. Objectives 1.) Learn the concepts of external costs and external benefits. 2.) Understand why the presence of externalities.
Externalities.
 Markets sometimes fail to allocate resources efficiently – some of these market failures are called externalities  An externality is when a person.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY An externality is … –the uncompensated impact of one person’s actions on the well-being.
EXTERNALITIES ETP Economics 101. E XTERNALITIES AND M ARKET I NEFFICIENCY (F AILURE ) An externality refers to the uncompensated impact of one person.
Externalities and Public Policy
Ch 28. Gov’t and Market Failure. Public Goods Nonrivalry – Once a producer has produced a public good, everyone can obtain the benefit. Nonrivalry – Once.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Mod Externalities as Market Failures & the “Fixes”
Across the country, countless people have protested, even risking arrest, against the Keystone XL Pipeline. (Credit: modification of image by “NoKXL”/Flickr.
Externalities >> chapter: 17 Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers 1 of 32.
14-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported.
Market Failure Chapter 14 Externalities. Economic Freedom Economic freedom refers to the degree to which private individuals are able to carry out voluntary.
Externalities as Market Failures & the “Fixes”
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Externalities Chapter 10 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 10 Externalities. Market Failure Market failure is when the free market does not provide the best outcome for society. Monopoly is a form of market.
THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR. Copyright©2004 South-Western Externalities.
PIGOU AND COASE The art of political economy. A.C. PIGOU
Chapter Externalities 10. Market Failure – When the free market may not provide economically efficient (ideal) outcome Sources – Too little competition.
Externalities. Maximized total benefit Recall: Adam Smith’s “invisible hand” of the marketplace leads self- interested buyers and sellers in a market.
4 THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR. Copyright©2004 South-Western 10 Externalities.
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
Externalities © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted.
THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR
Externalities.
Chapter 10 Externalities
10 Externalities.
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
10 Externalities.
10 Externalities.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
10 Externalities.
Ch 28. Gov’t and Market Failure
EXTERNALITIES ETP Economics 101.
Chapter 12 Environmental Protection and Negative Externalities
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Chapter 12 Environmental Protection and Negative Externalities
Presentation transcript:

12 | Environmental Protection and Negative Externalities The Economics of Pollution Command-and-Control Regulation Market-Oriented Environmental Tools The Benefits and Costs of U.S. Environmental Laws International Environmental Issues The Tradeoff between Economic Output and Environmental Protection

The problem of pollution arises for every economy in the world, whether high-income or low-income, and whether market oriented or command- oriented

Externalities Consider a concert producer who wants to build an outdoor arena that will host country music concerts a half- mile from your neighborhood. You will be able to hear these outdoor concerts while sitting on your back porch—or perhaps even in your dining room. In this case, the sellers and buyers of concert tickets may both be quite satisfied with their voluntary exchange, but you have no voice in their market transaction. The effect of a market exchange on a third party who is outside or “external” to the exchange is called an externality. Because externalities that occur in market transactions affect other parties beyond those involved, they are sometimes called spillovers. Externalities can be negative or positive. If you hate country music, then having it waft into your house every night would be a negative externality. If you love country music, then what amounts to a series of free concerts would be a positive externality

If the firm takes only its own costs of production into account, then its supply curve will be S private and the market equilibrium will occur at E 0. Accounting for additional external costs of $100 for every unit produced, the firm’s supply curve will be S public. The new equilibrium will occur at E 1. This shows that output and regulation are inversely related (at least ostensibly), but given the shift in supply, E 1 is nevertheless a more efficient outcome than E 0. It is important that all costs and benefits be included in determining whether the supply shifts significantly to the left.

However, when the externality of pollution exists, the supply curve no longer represents all social costs. Because externalities represent a case where markets no longer consider all social costs, but only some of them, economists commonly refer to externalities as an example of market failure. When there is market failure, the private market fails to achieve efficient output, because either firms do not account for all costs incurred in the production of output and/or consumers do not account for all benefits obtained (a positive externality). In the case of pollution, at the market output, social costs of production exceed social benefits to consumers, and the market produces too much of the product. We can see a general lesson here. If firms were required to pay the social costs of pollution, they would create less pollution, but they would also produce less of the product and they would charge a higher price.

Command-and-Control Regulation Command-and-control regulation has been highly successful in protecting and cleaning up the U.S. environment. However, economists have pointed out three difficulties with command-and-control environmental regulation. First, command-and-control regulation offers no incentive to improve the quality of the environment beyond the standard set by a particular law. Once the command-and-control regulation has been satisfied, polluters have zero incentive to do better. Second, command-and-control regulation is inflexible. Firms have no reason to rethink their production methods in fundamental ways that might reduce pollution even more and at lower cost. Third, command-and-control regulations are written by legislators and the EPA, and so they are subject to compromises in the political process. Real-world environmental laws are full of fine print, loopholes, and exceptions. Critics accept the goal of reducing pollution but question whether command-and-control regulation is the best way to design policy tools for accomplishing that goal.

Market-Oriented Environmental Tools (1) A pollution charge is a tax imposed on the quantity of pollution that a firm emits. A pollution charge gives a profit-maximizing firm an incentive to figure out ways to reduce its emissions—as long as the marginal cost of reducing the emissions is less than the tax. (2) When a city or state government sets up a marketable permit program (e.g. cap-and-trade), it must start by determining the overall quantity of pollution it will allow as it tries to meet national pollution standards. Then, a number of permits allowing only this quantity of pollution are divided among the firms that emit that pollutant. These permits to pollute can be sold or given to firms free. Now, add two more conditions. Imagine that these permits are designed to reduce total emissions over time. For example, a permit may allow emission of 10 units of pollution one year, but only nine units the next year, then eight units the year after that, and so on down to some lower level. In addition, imagine that these are marketable permits, meaning that firms can buy and sell them. (3) Strengthened property rights can also strike a balance between economic activity and pollution.

Coase Theorem The theorem states that if trade in an externality is possible and there are sufficiently low transaction costs, bargaining will lead to an efficient outcome regardless of the initial allocation of property. The Coase theorem is considered an important basis for most modern economic analyses of government regulation. The Coase theorem came from the regulation of radio frequencies. Competing radio stations could use the same frequencies and would therefore interfere with each other's broadcasts. The problem faced by regulators was how to eliminate interference and allocate frequencies to radio stations efficiently. Coase proposed that as long as property rights in these frequencies were well defined, it ultimately did not matter if adjacent radio stations interfered with each other by broadcasting in the same frequency band. Furthermore, it did not matter to whom the property rights were granted. The station able to reap the higher economic gain from broadcasting would have an incentive to pay the other station not to interfere. In the absence of transaction costs, both stations would strike a mutually advantageous deal. It would not matter which station had the initial right to broadcast; eventually, the right to broadcast would end up with the party that was able to put it to the most highly valued use. Of course, the parties themselves would care who was granted the rights initially because this allocation would impact their wealth, but the end result of who broadcasts would not change because the parties would trade to the outcome that was overall most efficient. This counterintuitive insight — that the initial imposition of legal entitlement is irrelevant because the parties will eventually reach the same result — is Coase’s invariance thesis.

The Tradeoff between Economic Output and Environmental Protection Each society will have to weigh its own values and decide whether it prefers a choice like P with more economic output and less environmental protection, or a choice like T with more environmental protection and less economic output.

Global warming and biodiversity are examples of international externalities