Principles and Preferences Chapter 4 Principles and Preferences
Main Topics Principles of decision-making Consumer preferences Substitution between goods Utility
Principles of Decision Making Predicting consumers’ choices. Why do consumers make different choices? All are related to Preferences.
1st assumption about consumer behavior: The Ranking Principle: A consumer can rank in order of preferences, all available alternatives. A consumer is indifferent between 2 alternatives if he likes them both equally.
The 2nd assumption: The Choice Principle: Among all available alternatives, the consumer selects the one that he ranks the highest. this means that the consumer always attempts to achieve the highest level of satisfaction.
Consumer Preferences Decisions are tend to be interrelated: the enjoyment of one activity usually depends on other activities. when spending money on one good, there is less money to spend on other goods. Consumption bundle: a collection of goods an individual consumes over a given period.
Ranking Consumption Bundles Only the consumer who can rank his own consumption bundles. The 3rd Principle of consumer decision making: The “More preferred to Less” Principle: When one consumption bundle contains more of every good than a second bundle, a consumer prefers the 1st bundle t the 2nd.
SOUP X’S ALTERNATIVES AND PREFERENCES 11 7 3 1 13 8 4 2 15 9 6 5 16 14 12 10 3 2 BREAD 1 1 2 3 NOTE: 1 IS THE HIGHEST
SOUP X’S ALTERNATIVES AND PREFERENCES 11 7 3 1 13 8 4 2 15 9 6 5 16 14 12 10 3 2 1st BEST? 2nd BEST? LEAST PREFERRED BUNDLE? BREAD 1 1 2 3
SOUP X’S ALTERNATIVES AND PREFERENCES 11 7 3 1 13 8 4 2 15 9 6 5 16 14 12 10 3 2 BREAD 1 X GENERALLY PREFERS SOUP TO BREAD MPL??? 1 2 3
SOUP X’S ALTERNATIVES AND PREFERENCES 11 7 3 1 13 8 4 2 15 9 6 5 16 14 12 10 3 2 BREAD 1 X GENERALLY PREFERS SOUP TO BREAD 1 2 3 IN-TEXT-EXERCISE 4.1
Building Blocks of Consumer Theory Preferences tell us about a consumer’s likes and dislikes A consumer is indifferent between two alternatives if she likes (or dislikes) them equally The Ranking Principle: A consumer can rank, in order of preference, all potentially available alternatives The Choice Principle: Among available alternatives, the consumer chooses the one that he ranks the highest
The Consumer’s Problem Consumer’s economic problems is to allocate limited funds to competing needs and desires over some time period Chooses a consumption bundle Should reflect preferences over various bundles, not just feelings about any one good in isolation Decision to consume more of one good is a decision to consume less of another
Principles of Consumer Decision-Making The More-is-better Principle: When one consumption bundle contains more of every good than a second bundle, a consumer prefers the first bundle to the second Transitivity: if a > b and b > c, then a > c.
Indifference Curves Use when goods are (or assumed to be) available in any fraction of a unit Represent alternatives graphically or mathematically rather than in a table Starting with any alternative, an indifference curve shows all the other alternatives a consumer likes equally well
Figure 4.1: Identifying Alternatives and Indifference Curves
Properties of Indifference Curves Thin Do not slope upward Separates bundles that are better from bundles that are worse than those that are on the indifference curve
Figure 4.2: Indifference Curves Ruled Out by the More-is-better Principle
Families of Indifference Curves Collection of indifference curves that represent the preferences of an individual Do not cross Comparing two bundles, the consumer prefers the one on the indifference curve further from the origin
Figure 4.3: A Family of Indifference Curves
Figure 4.4: Indifference Curves Do Not Cross
Formulas for Indifference Curves More complete and precise to describe preferences mathematically For example, can write a formula for a consumer’s indifference curves Formula describes an entire family of indifference curves Each indifference curve represents a particular level of well-being Higher levels of well-being are on indifference curves further from the origin
Figure 4.6: Plotting Indifference Curves Formula for indifference curves is B = U/S (Starting from U=B*S) U is well-being, or “utility” To find a particular curve, plug in a value for U, then plot the relationship between B and S
Substitution Between Goods Economic decisions involve trade-offs To determine whether a consumer has made the best choice, we need to know the rate at which she is willing to make trade-offs between different goods Indifference curves provide that information
Rates of Substitution Consider moving along an indifference curve, from one bundle to another This is the same as subtracting units of one good and compensating the consumer for the loss by adding units of another good Slope of the indifference curve shows how much of the second good is needed to make up for the decrease in the first good
Figure 4.8: Rates of Substitution Look at move from bundle A to C Consumer gains 1 soup; gains 2 bread Willing to substitute for soup with bread at 2 ounces per pint
Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution for X with Y, MRSXY, is the rate at which a consumer must adjust Y to maintain the same level of well-being when X changes by a tiny amount, from a given starting point Tells us how much Y a consumer needs to compensate for losing a little bit of X Tells us how much Y to take away to compensate for gaining a little bit of X
Figure 4.9: Marginal Rate of Substitution MRSSB=-∆B/∆S=-3/2
What Determines Rates of Substitution? Differences in tastes Preferences for one good over another affect the slope of an indifference curve (weights attached to each good in the utility function) Implications for MRS Starting point on the indifference curve People like variety so most indifference curves get flatter as we move from top left to bottom right Link between slope and MRS implies that MRS declines; the amount of Y required to compensate for a given change in X decreases
Figure 4.10: Indifference Curves and Consumer Tastes
Figure 4.11: MRS along an Indifference Curve
Formulas for MRS MRS formula tells us the rate at which a consumer will exchange one good for another, given the amounts consumed Every indifference curve formula has an MRS formula that describes the same preferences Indifference curves: B=U/S; MRSSB=B/S
Perfect Substitutes and Complements Some special cases of preferences represent opposites ends of the substitutability spectrum Two products are perfect substitutes if their functions are identical; a consumer is willing to swap one for the other at a fixed rate Two products are perfect complements if they are valuable only when used together in fixed proportions Note that the goods do not have to be exchanged one-for-one!
Figure 4.12: Perfect Substitutes
Figure 4.13: Perfect Complements
Sample Problem 1 (4.3): Gary has two children, Kevin and Dora. Each one consumes “yummies” and nothing else. Gary loves both children equally. For example, he is equally happy when Kevin has two yummies and Dora has three, or when Kevin has three yummies and Dora has two. But he is happier when their consumption is more equal. Draw Gary’s indifference curves. What would they look like if he loved one child more than the other?
Utility Summarizes everything that is known about a consumer’s preferences Utility is a numeric value indicating the consumer’s relative well-being Recall that the consumer’s goal is to benefit from the goods and services she uses Can describe the value a consumer gets from consumption bundles mathematically through a utility function
Utility Functions and Indifference Curves Utility functions must assign the same value to all bundles on the same indifference curve Must also give higher utility values to indifference curves further from the origin Can start with information about preferences and derive a utility function Or can begin with a utility function and construct indifference curves Can also think of indifference curves as “contour lines” for different levels of utility
Figure 4.14: Representing Preferences with a Utility Function
Sample Problem 2: For example assume preferences are described by the following utility function: U = X1/2Y1/2 To plot an indifference curve for this utility function, first isolate Y: U2 = XY Y = U2 /X Then pick some level of utility. Let’s set U = 25
Utility Functions and Indifference Curves Thus, Y = 5/X When X = 1, Y = 25 When X = 2, Y = 12.5 When X = 3, Y = 8.33 When X = 4, Y = 6.25 When X = 5, Y = 5 And so on… Describe the indifference curves for the following utility functions: U = X + Y U = min(X,Y)
Ordinal vs. Cardinal Utility Information about preferences can be ordinal or cardinal Ordinal information allows us to determine only whether one alternative is better than another Cardinal information reveals the intensity of preferences, “How much worse or better?” Utility functions are intended to summarize ordinal information Scale of utility functions is arbitrary; changing scale does not change the underlying preferences
Marginal Utility To make a link between MRS and utility, need a new concept Marginal utility is the change in a consumer’s utility resulting from the addition of a very small amount of some good, divided by the amount added
Utility Functions and MRS Small change in X, ∆X, causes utility to change by MUX∆X Small change in Y, ∆Y, causes utility to change by MUY∆Y If we stay on same indifference curve, then –∆Y/∆X =MUX/MUY
Marginal Rate of Substitution Let’s find the MRS for each of the following utility functions: U = X1/2Y1/2; MUX=(1/2)X-1/2Y1/2 and MUY =(1/2) X1/2Y-1/2 U = X1/3Y2/3 MUX=(1/3)X-2/3Y2/3 and MUY =(2/3) X1/3Y-1/3 U = X + Y MUX = Y and MUY = X
Sample Problem 3 (4.14): Latanya likes to talk on the telephone. We can represent her preferences with the utility function U(B,J) = 18B + 20J, where B and J are minutes of conversation per month with Bill and Jackie, respectively. If Latanya plans to use the phone for one hour to talk with only one person, with whom would she rather speak? Why? What is the formula for her indifference curves?