Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus How to estimate preferences or utility from demand A discrete good with quasilinear utility u(x,y)=v(x)+y where y is money.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Advertisements

Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
Social welfare and price changes Udayan Roy ECO61 Microeconomic Analysis Fall 2008.
Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes
Consumer’s and Producer’s Surpluses
Valuation 2 and 3: Demand and welfare theory
Chapter 36 Public Goods Suppose there are two nonsmokers and one smoker. Even if nonsmokers are entitled to clean air, they first have to agree among themselves.
Chapter 13 – Taxation and Efficiency
Chapter 13: Taxation and Efficiency Econ 330: Public Finance Dr
Labor-Leisure Choice – Indifference Curves Graph by Harcourt, Inc. Just like the indifference curves used to derive consumer demand. Tradeoff is between.
Consumer and Producer Surplus in Benefit-Cost Analysis (Campbell & Brown Chapter 7) Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics UQ, St. Lucia 2003.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  Suppose you know you can buy as much gasoline as you choose at a given price.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Welfare measurement: individual CS, CV, EV and PS
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
Consumer Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  Basic idea of consumer surplus: We want a measure of how much a person is willing to pay for.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Consumer’s Surplus 消费者剩余.  In previous chapters  From underlying preference or utility function to consumer’s demand function  In practice,  From.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
The Welfare Analysis of Free Trade The fact that a nation unequivocally gains from international trade does not mean that all groups within the nation.
Chapter Ten Intertemporal Choice. u Persons often receive income in “lumps”; e.g. monthly salary. u How is a lump of income spread over the following.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per litre once you enter the.
Welfare measures: CS, CV, EV and PS (Course Micro-economics) Ch 14 Varian Teachers: Jongeneel/Van Mouche.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Who Wants to be an Economist? Notice: questions in the exam will not have this kind of multiple choice format. The type of exercises in the exam will.
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
Elasticity and Consumer Surplus
1 Consumer Choice and Demand Chapter 6 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
How much is a consumer hurt by an increase in price (like a tax)? Three Methods to measure this: Change Consumer Surplus. Compensating Variation –The amount.
ECMB36 LECTURE NOTES MEASURING CHANGES IN SOCIAL WELFARE Townley, Chapter 5.
Frank Cowell: Consumer Welfare CONSUMER: WELFARE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July Almost essential Consumer Optimisation.
Welfare Economics Consumer and Producer Surplus. Consumer Surplus How much are you willing to pay for a pair of jeans? As an individual consumer, you.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Consumer: Welfare MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Firm: Optimisation Consumption: Basics.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Public Policy Analysis MPA 404 Lecture 16. Previous Lecture  A revision of the concepts of equilibrium.  The short run disequilibrium, and the long.
Consumption, Production, Welfare B: Consumer Behaviour Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester 2013.
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
Measuring Welfare Changes of Individuals Exact Utility Indicators –Equivalent Variation (EV) –Compensating Variation (CV) Relationship between Exact Utility.
CDAE Class 10 Sept. 28 Last class: 3. Individual demand curves Today: 3. Individual demand curves Quiz 3 (Sections 3.1 – 3.4) Next class: 3.Individual.
Microeconomics 2 Answers to the first 17 questions on the First Specimen Examination Paper (the remaining 10 answers are elsewhere)
 Consumer welfare from a good is the benefit a consumer gets from consuming that good in excess of the cost of the good.  If you buy a good for exactly.
Chapter 5 Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis
CDAE Class 10 Sept. 27 Last class: 3. Individual demand curves Today: 3. Individual demand curves Class exercise Next class: 3.Individual demand.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p): at any given price p, how many units.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Individual & Market Demand Chapter 4. 4 main topics related to Individual & Market Demand 1. Use the Rational Choice model Derive an individual’s demand.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Endowments. 2 Buying and Selling Trade involves exchange -- when something is bought something else must be sold. What will be bought? What will be.
Frank Cowell: EC202 Microeconomics Revision Lecture 2 EC202: Microeconomic Principles II Frank Cowell May 2008.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Exercise 4.12 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell November 2006.
CONSUMER EQUILIBRIUM AND MARKET DEMAND Chapter 4.
Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Intertemporal Choice.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Chapter 8 SLUTSKY EQUATION. Substitution Effect and Income Effect x1x1 x2x2 m/p 2 m’/p 2 X Y Z Substitution Effect Income Effect Shift Pivot.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
Measuring Welfare Changes of Individuals
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus How to estimate preferences or utility from demand A discrete good with quasilinear utility u(x,y)=v(x)+y where y is money to be spent on other goods and its price is normalized to be 1. Have seen before that the consumer will start to buy the first unit at the r 1 so that v(1)+m- r 1 =v(0)+m or r 1 =v(1)-v(0)

Following this logic, r 1 =v(1)-v(0), r 2 =v(2)-v(1), r 3 =v(3)-v(2) and so on. Therefore, if we sum the area under the demand curve say up to the third unit, then we get r 1 + r 2 + r 3 =v(3)-v(0). This is the change in utility due to the increase in consumption of x. If the consumer can get these three units for free, then his utility change (from consuming zero unit to consuming three units for free) will be v(3)+m-(v(0)+m)=v(3)-v(0), exactly the area under the demand.

Suppose the price of x is p, then the utility change when the consumer buys three units of x is v(3)+m-3p- (v(0)+m)=v(3)-v(0)-3p. This is the area that lies between the demand and the price (up to three units) and is called the consumer’s surplus. Alternatively, can think in the following way. For the first unit, the consumer is willing to pay up to r 1 but he only pays p, so there is this surplus r 1 –p for the first unit.

Similarly, there is a surplus of r 2 –p for the second unit and r 3 –p for the third unit. So when he consumes 3 units, his consumer’s surplus is r 1 -p+r 2 -p+r 3 - p=v(3)-v(0)-3p. Can think of a continuous demand using the discrete approximation or solve max v(x)+y s.t. px+y=m.

Fig. 14.1

MRS xy =v’(x)/1=p/1 so plotting the demand (the price) is the same as plotting v’(x). If the consumer consumes up to 3 units, then his change in utility is v(3)+m- 3p-(v(0)+m)=v(3)-v(0)-3p= ∫ 0 3 v’(x)dx-3p. This is the area that lies between the demand curve and the price (up to three units) and is the consumer’s surplus. Interpret the change in consumer’s surplus the same way.

Fig. 14.2

Suppose the price changes from p to p’ and accordingly the consumer changes consumption from x to x’. The CS (up to x) is the change of utility from not buying to buying x units. Similarly, the CS (up to x’) is the change of utility from not buying to buying x’ units. Hence the difference CS(x’)-CS(x) is the change of utility from buying x units to buying x’ units. It consists of a rectangular area and a roughly triangular area.

Fig. 14.3

Suppose we have estimated a utility function from a demand, there are two useful utility function worth mentioning because they lead to measurement of the welfare change expressed in dollar units. It is convenient to have some monetary measures of utility. Consider a price change from p to p’. Then the change in income necessary to restore the consumer to his original indifference curve is called the compensating variation (CV).

Fig. 14.4

This is measuring the two indifference curves by p’. Alternatively, we can ask how much money would have to be taken away from the consumer before the price change to leave him as well off as he would be after the price change. This is called the equivalent variation (EV). This is measuring the two indifference curves by p. (mention three lines)

One example. u(x,y)=x 0.5 y 0.5 and price of y is 1. Suppose price of x changes from 1 to 2 and income is 100. CV: =(0.5m/2) 0.5 (0.5m/1) 0.5, so m=141. You have to give the consumer additional 41 dollars to make him as well off as before. EV: =(0.5m/1) 0.5 (0.5m/1) 0.5, so m=70. You have to take 30 dollars away from the consumer to make him as well off as after the price change.

Note further that for quasilinear preferences, since it does not matter which price vector we use to measure the distance between two indifference curves, so CV and EV will be the same.

Using the same example, suppose the consumer’s consumption changes from x to x’ (with some abuse of notation). CV: v(x)+m-px=v(x’)+m-p’x’+C so C=v(x)-v(x’)+p’x’-px EV: v(x’)+m-p’x’=v(x)+m-px-E so E=v(x)-v(x’)+p’x’-px=C=-ΔCS

Fig. 14.5

Producer’s surplus can be approached the same way. Can think of selling endowment. Suppose a consumer has n units of good x. When will he start selling the first unit of x? Must be v(n)+m=v(n- 1)+m+r 1. So r 1 =v(n)-v(n-1). Similarly, he will start selling the second unit at v(n-1)+m+r 2 =v(n-2)+m+2r 2, or r 2 =v(n-1)-v(n-2).

Hence if for the first unit, he is selling at r 1, then he is indifferent between selling or not selling. If the market price is p, then he gets a surplus of p-r 1 for the first unit. Thus the area between the price and the supply curve measures the producer’s surplus from selling (compared to not selling). When moving from consumer’s surplus to consumers’ surplus, we can aggregate the consumer’s surplus across consumers.

Fig. 14.6

Yet we may care about the distribution of the welfare change, i.e., which consumer gets better off and which gets worse off (a tax change making the poor better off may be preferred by the society to that making the rich better off, for instance). In this case, we may use the convenient measures of CV and EV. Say a policy change makes A worse off by 3 dollars and B better off by 4 dollars (using the CV measure), then we may want to do it depending on who A and B are (mention redistribution).

Some comments on CS. Budget constraint may kick in. Look at the case where u(x,y)=x 1/2 +y and m=1. r 4 should be 4 1/2 -3 1/2 =0.2679, but 4r 4 >1. Look at some other utility function say u(x,y)=x 0.5 y 0.5, the price of y is 1 and income 100. The demand curve is x=50/p x. If p x changes from 2 to 1, the increase of utility is = Yet the change of CS is ∫ (50/x)dx=