Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year 2014-2015 Lecture 4: From capital/income ratios to capital.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Review of Exam 1.
Advertisements

Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 7: The regulation of capital and inequality.
Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries Thomas Piketty & Gabriel Zucman Paris School of Economics September 2012.
Labor Markets FIN 30220: Macroeconomic Analysis Of the 317 million people that make up the US population, approximately 246 million are considered by.
A closed economy, market-clearing model
Profit-Maximization. Economic Profit u Profit maximization provides the rationale for firms to choose the feasible production plan. u Profit is the difference.
PROBLEMS Return to Capital Remain High. Saving Rate Remain High. Foreign Surplus growth fast. How to Solve This Puzzle ?
Government Control of Prices in What Are the Actual Outcomes?
In this chapter, we learn:
Intermediate Macroeconomics
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Six Firms and Production.
Macroeconomics Chapter 91 Capital Utilization and Unemployment C h a p t e r 9.
The Theory and Estimation of Production
Chapter 7 Valuation Concepts © 2005 Thomson/South-Western.
Microeconomics for International Trade Theory
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND GROWTH: THE BASIC SOLOW MODEL Chapter 3 – first lecture Introducing Advanced Macroeconomics:
Introduction In the last lecture we defined and measured some key macroeconomic variables. Now we start building theories about what determines these key.
Lecture 4: The Demand for Labor
MACROECONOMICS AND THE GLOBAL BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT The Wealth of Nations The Supply Side.
Public Economics: Tax & Transfer Policies (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 2: Tax incidence:
Copyright © 2001 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Slide Saving and Capital Formation.
Should the Rich Pay for Fiscal Adjustment? Income and Capital Tax Options Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Brussels, ECFIN Workshop, October 18.
Fighting inequality in society through tax policy Income and Capital Tax Options Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Brussels, Progressive Economy.
Money, Output, and Prices Classical vs. Keynesians.
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
The Demand For Resources Chapter 12 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Define GDP and explain why the value of production,
Neoclassical production function
Economic History (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 2: The dynamics of capital accumulation:
Section 3 – Theory of the Firm
How much does the economy produce? The quantity that an economy will produce depends on two things-  The quantity of inputs utilized in the production.
Source: Mankiw (2000) Macroeconomics, Chapter 3 p Distribution of National Income Factors of production and production function determine output.
ECNE610 Managerial Economics APRIL Dr. Mazharul Islam Chapter-6.
Chapter SixCopyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall. 1 Chapter 6 The Theory and Estimation of Production.
Review of the previous Lecture The overall level of prices can be measured by either 1. the Consumer Price Index (CPI), the price of a fixed basket of.
Stock Valuation.
1 ITFD Growth and Development LECTURE SLIDES SET 5 Professor Antonio Ciccone.
Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 3: The dynamics of capital/income.
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 1: Income, capital and growth (Tuesday.
Theory of the Firm 1) How a firm makes cost- minimizing production decisions. 2) How its costs vary with output. Chapter 6: Production: How to combine.
1 Macroeconomics LECTURE SLIDES SET 5 Professor Antonio Ciccone Macroeconomics Set 5.
Chapter 6 The Theory and Estimation of Production
Perfect Competition A perfectly competitive industry is one that obeys the following assumptions:  there are a large number of firms, each producing the.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 3 National Income Outline of model A closed economy, market-clearing model Supply side  factor markets (supply, demand, price)  determination.
Next page Chapter 5: The Demand for Labor. Jump to first page 1. Derived Demand for Labor.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
1 Macroeconomics BGSE/UPF LECTURE SLIDES SET 5 Professor Antonio Ciccone.
Chapter 17: Capital and Financial Markets. Capital Capital = buildings and equipment used to produce output Do not confuse capital with “financial capital”
CHAPTER 3 NATIONAL INCOME: WHERE IT COMES FROM AND WHERE IT GOES ECN 2003 MACROECONOMICS 1 Assoc. Prof. Yeşim Kuştepeli.
1 Resource Markets CHAPTER 11 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 1: Income, capital and growth (Tuesday.
Macroeconomics Chapter 31 Introduction to Economic Growth C h a p t e r 3.
Inequality & Capitalism in the Long-Run Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics HONG KONG, October 18 th 2013.
CHAPTER OUTLINE Unemployment Measuring Unemployment Components of the Unemployment Rate The Costs of Unemployment Inflation The Consumer Price Index The.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 3-1 Chapter Outline The Production Function The Demand for Labor The Supply of Labor Labor Market Equilibrium.
National Income and Price Determination Macro Unit III.
MACROECONOMICS © 2011 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved S E V E N T H E D I T I O N PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw C H A P.
Test Review Econ 322 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
Next page Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 5 The Demand for Labor.
Principles of Macroeconomics Lecture 9 ECONOMIC GROWTH & DEVELOPMENT
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Define GDP and explain why the value of production,
1 Teaching Innovation - Entrepreneurial - Global The Centre for Technology enabled Teaching & Learning, N Y S S, India DTEL DTEL (Department for Technology.
LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMICS ECO306 FALL 2011 GHASSAN DIBEH.
Chapter 5 The Demand for Labor McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter 17: Capital and Financial Markets
Perfect Competition: Short Run and Long Run
The Costs of Production
Macroeconomics Chapter 9
Presentation transcript:

Economics of Inequality (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year Lecture 4: From capital/income ratios to capital shares (Tuesday October 14 th 2014) (check on line for updated versions)on line

Capital-income ratios β vs. capital shares α Capital/income ratio β=K/Y Capital share α = Y K /Y with Y K = capital income (=sum of rent, dividends, interest, profits, etc.: i.e. all incomes going to the owners of capital, independently of any labor input) I.e. β = ratio between capital stock and income flow While α = share of capital income in total income flow By definition: α = r x β With r = Y K /K = average real rate of return to capital If β=600% and r=5%, then α = 30% = typical values

In practice, the average rate of return to capital r (typically r≈4-5%) varies a lot across assets and over individuals (more on this in Lecture 6) Typically, rental return on housing = 3-4% (i.e. the rental value of an appartment worth € is generally about €/year) (+ capital gain or loss) Return on stock market (dividend + k gain) = as much as 6-7% in the long run Return on bank accounts or cash = as little as 1-2% (but only a small fraction of total wealth) Average return across all assets and individuals ≈ 4-5%

The Cobb-Douglas production function Cobb-Douglas production function: Y = F(K,L) = K α L 1-α With perfect competition, wage rate v = marginal product of labor, rate of return r = marginal product of capital: r = F K = α K α-1 L 1-α and v = F L = (1-α) K α L -α Therefore capital income Y K = r K = α Y & labor income Y L = v L = (1-α) Y I.e. capital & labor shares are entirely set by technology (say, α=30%, 1-α=70%) and do not depend on quantities K, L Intuition: Cobb-Douglas ↔ elasticity of substitution between K & L is exactly equal to 1 I.e. if v/r rises by 1%, K/L=α/(1-α) v/r also rises by 1%. So the quantity response exactly offsets the change in prices: if wages ↑by 1%, then firms use 1% less labor, so that labor share in total output remains the same as before

The limits of Cobb-Douglas Economists like Cobb-Douglas production function, because stable capital shares are approximately stable However it is only an approximation: in practice, capital shares α vary in the 20-40% range over time and between countries (or even sometime in the 10-50% range) In 19c, capital shares were closer to 40%; in 20c, they were closer to 20-30%; structural rise of human capital (i.e. exponent α↓ in Cobb-Douglas production function Y = K α L 1-α ?), or purely temporary phenomenon ? Over period, capital shares have increased from % to 25-30% in rich countries : very difficult to explain with Cobb-Douglas framework

The CES production function CES = a simple way to think about changing capital shares CES : Y = F(K,L) = [a K ( σ-1)/σ + b L ( σ-1)/σ ] σ/(σ-1) with a, b = constant σ = constant elasticity of substitution between K and L σ →∞: linear production function Y = r K + v L (infinite substitution: machines can replace workers and vice versa, so that the returns to capital and labor do not fall at all when the quantity of capital or labor rise) ( = robot economy) σ →0: F(K,L)=min(rK,vL) (fixed coefficients) = no substitution possibility: one needs exactly one machine per worker σ →1: converges toward Cobb-Douglas; but all intermediate cases are also possible: Cobb-Douglas is just one possibility among many Compute the first derivative r = F K : the marginal product to capital is given by r = F K = a β -1/ σ (with β=K/Y) I.e. r ↓ as β↑ (more capital makes capital less useful), but the important point is that the speed at which r ↓ depends on σ

With r = F K = a β -1/ σ, the capital share α is given by: α = r β = a β ( σ -1)/ σ I.e. α is an increasing function of β if and only if σ>1 (and stable iff σ=1) The important point is that with large changes in the volume of capital β, small departures from σ=1 are enough to explain large changes in α If σ = 1.5, capital share rises from α=28% to α =36% when β rises from β=250% to β =500% = more or less what happened since the 1970s In case β reaches β =800%, α would reach α =42% In case σ =1.8, α would be as large as α =53%

Measurement problems with capital shares In many ways, β is easier to measure than α In principle, capital income = all income flows going to capital owners (independanty of any labor input); labor income = all income flows going to labor earners (independantly of any capital input) But in practice, the line is often hard to draw: family firms, self- semployed workers, informal financial intermediation costs (=the time spent to manage one’s own portfolio) If one measures the capital share α from national accounts (rent+dividend+interest+profits) and compute average return r=α/β, then the implied r often looks very high for a pure return to capital ownership: it probably includes a non-negligible entrepreneurial labor component, particularly in reconstruction periods with low β and high r; the pure return might be 20-30% smaller (see estimates) Maybe one should use two-sector models Y=Y h +Y b (housing + business); return to housing = closer to pure return to capital

Recent work on capital shares Imperfect competition and globalization: see Karabarmounis-Neiman 2013, « The Global Decline in the Labor Share »; see also KN2014 Karabarmounis-Neiman 2013KN2014 Public vs private firms: see Azmat-Manning- Van Reenen 2011, « Privatization and the Decline of the Labor Share in GDP: A Cross- Country Aanalysis of the Network Industries »Azmat-Manning- Van Reenen 2011 Capital shares and CEO pay: see Pursey 2013, « CEO Pay and Factor shares: Bargaining effects in US corporations »Pursey 2013

Summing up The rate of return to capital r is determined mostly by technology: r = F K = marginal product to capital, elasticity of substitution σ The quantity of capital β is determined by saving attitudes and by growth (=fertility + innovation): β = s/g The capital share is determined by the product of the two: α = r x β Anything can happen

Note: the return to capital r=F K is dermined not only by technology but also by psychology, i.e. saving attitudes s=s(r) might vary with the rate of return In models with wealth or bequest in the utility function U(c t,w t+1 ), there is zero saving elasticity with U(c,w)=c 1-s w s, but with more general functional forms on can get any elasticity In pure lifecycle model, the saving rate s is primarily determined by demographic structure (more time in retirement → higher s), but it can also vary with the rate of return, in particular if the rate of return becomes very low (say, below 2%) or very high (say, above 6%)

In the dynastic utility model, the rate of return is entirely set by the rate of time preference (=psychological parameter) and the growth rate: Max Σ U(c t )/(1+δ) t, with U(c)=c 1-1/ξ /(1-1/ξ) → unique long rate rate of return r t → r = δ +ξg > g (ξ>1 and transverality condition) This holds both in the representative agent version of model and in the heteogenous agent version (with insurable shocks); more on this in Lecture 6