Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 1 of 25 Marginal Analysis Purposes:

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Cost and Production Chapters 6 and 7.
Advertisements

Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics, 9e Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice.
Chapter 9: Production and Cost in the Long Run
1 Chapter 7 Behind the Supply Curve: 2 Recall: Optimal Consumer Behavior Consumer Behavior –(behind the demand curve): Consumption of G&S (Q) produces.
Chapter 9 Costs.
Frank Cowell: Firm Basics THE FIRM: BASICS MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell March
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Six Firms and Production.
Support Vector Machines Formulation  Solve the quadratic program for some : min s. t.,, denotes where or membership.  Different error functions and measures.
Chapter 8 Costs © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Definitions of Costs It is important to differentiate between accounting cost and economic cost the accountant’s view of cost stresses out-of-pocket expenses,
Linear Programming Econ Outline  Review the basic concepts of Linear Programming  Illustrate some problems which can be solved by linear programming.
Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Flaw of Averages Slide 1 of 29 Richard de Neufville.
Definition and Properties of the Production Function Lecture II.
Chapter 8. COSTS McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 8.
Applied Economics for Business Management
Chapter 10 McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
1 Least Cost System Operation: Economic Dispatch 2 Smith College, EGR 325 March 10, 2006.
Chapter 8 Cost Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill.
The Production Process and Costs
Lecture #7. Lecture Outline Review Go over Exam #1 Continue production economic theory.
Topic on Production and Cost Functions and Their Estimation.
Managerial Economics Managerial Economics = economic theory + mathematical eco + statistical analysis.
Cobb-Douglas Production Function
Chapter 5 Production analysis and policy. KEY CONCEPTS production function discrete production function continuous production function returns to scale.
10.1 Chapter 10 –Theory of Production and Cost in the Long Run(LR)  The theory of production in the LR provides the theoretical basis for firm decision-making.
Chapter 6 Production. The Production Function A production function tells us the maximum output a firm can produce (in a given period) given available.
THE THEORY OF PRODUCTION
Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Production Function Slide 1 of 34 Production Functions.
WELCOME TO THETOPPERSWAY.COM.
11. Cost minimization Econ 494 Spring 2013.
Sequences and Series. Limits. Differential Calculus. Partial derivatives. Lagrangian multiplier. September 2011.
1 Cost Minimization and Cost Curves Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1.
Chapter 8 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Costs.
Lecture Notes. Cost Minimization Before looked at maximizing Profits (π) = TR – TC or π =pf(L,K) – wL – rK But now also look at cost minimization That.
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Supply: the firm Firms have to decide (at least) two things: (1) How to produce and (2) How much to produce. (If a monopolist.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. This week: The Firm Tuesday Chapter 11: Cost minimisation and the demand for factors. Wednesday Chapter 12: Cost curves.
MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell
STDM - Linear Programming 1 By Isuru Manawadu B.Sc in Accounting Sp. (USJP), ACA, AFM
Nonlinear Programming
Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Dynamic Programming Slide 1 of 35 Dynamic Programming.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. An overview...of the first two parts of the course......of the most important points.
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2015 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London September 2013.
Chapter 9 Production Functions
Applied Economics for Business Management Lecture #8.
Lecture 7 and 8 The efficient and optimal use of natural resources.
Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Drypressing Cost Model Slide 1 of 8 Drypressing Cost.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Chapter 13: totals In totals space, areas do not mean anything. slopes do – the corresponding marginal. Think of the units.
ECN 145 Lecture 12 Transportation Economics: Production and Costs I.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Plan for today 1.We look at the Homework I set at the end of Lecture We will quickly revise the relationships between.
1 Chapters 8: Costs of Production. 2 Cost Definitions Total cost (TC) = all costs of production –If r is the cost of capital (rental cost), and w is the.
CDAE Class 17 Oct. 23 Last class: Result of the midterm exam 5. Production functions Today: 5. Production functions Next class: 5.Production functions.
Linear Programming Short-run decision making model –Optimizing technique –Purely mathematical Product prices and input prices fixed Multi-product production.
Production Economics Chapter 7
Linear Programming Department of Business Administration FALL by Asst. Prof. Sami Fethi.
Review Class Seven Producer theory  Key sentence: A representative, or say, typical firm will maximize his profit under the restriction of technology.
Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville  Massachusetts Institute of Technology Review for Mid-termSlide 1 of 14 Review of 1st half.
Theory of Production Topic 4. Outline There are 3 major issues to be addressed by the theory of Production – Production behaviour in the short run – Production.
9-1 Learning Objectives  Graph a typical production isoquant and discuss the properties of isoquants  Construct isocost curves  Use optimization theory.
Production and Cost in the Long Run Nihal Hennayake.
1 Chapter 7: Costs and Cost Minimization Consumers purchase GOODS to maximize their utility. This consumption depends upon a consumer’s INCOME and the.
Chapter 9 Production and Cost in the Long Run
Architectural Design Space Exploration
Chapter 5: Production and Cost
Marginal Analysis and Economies of Scale
Marginal Analysis Purposes:
Marginal Analysis Purposes:
Marginal Analysis Purposes:
Review of 1st half of course
Presentation transcript:

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 1 of 25 Marginal Analysis Purposes: 1.To present a basic application of constrained optimization 2. Apply to Production Function to get criteria and patterns of optimal system design

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 2 of 25 Marginal Analysis: Outline 1.Definition and Assumptions 2.Optimality criteria  Analysis  Interpretation  Application 3.Key concepts  Expansion path  Cost function  Economies of scale 4.Summary

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 3 of 25 Marginal Analysis: Concept l Basic form of optimization of design l Combines: Production function - Technical efficiency Input cost function, c(X) Economic efficiency

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 4 of 25 Marginal Analysis: Assumptions l Feasible region is convex (over relevant portion) This is key. Why?  To guarantee no other optimum missed l No constraints on resources  To define a general solution l Models are “analytic” (continuously differentiable)  Finds optimum by looking at margins -- derivatives

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 5 of 25 Optimality Conditions for Design, by Marginal Analysis The Problem: Min C(Y’) = c(X) cost of inputs for any level of output, Y’ s.t. g(X) = Y’ production function The Lagrangean: L = c(X) - [g(X) - Y’] vector of resources Fixed level of output

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 6 of 25 Optimality Conditions for Design: Results l Key Result:  c(X) /  X i =  g(X) /  X i l Optimality Conditions: MP i / MC i = MP j / MC j = 1 / MC j / MP j = MC i / MP i = = Shadow Price on Product l A Each X i contributes “same bang for buck” balanced design marginal costmarginal product

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 7 of 25 Optimality Conditions: Graphical Interpretation of Costs (A) Input Cost Function X2X2 X1X1 P2P2 P1P1 B/P 2 B/P 1 Linear Case: B = Budget c(X) =  p i X i  B General case: Budget is non-linear (as in curved line)

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 8 of 25 Optimality Conditions: Graphical Interpretation of Results (B) Conditions X2X2 X1X1 Slope = MRS ij = - MP 1 / MP 2 = - MC 1 / MC 2 Isoquant $

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 9 of 25 Application of Optimality Conditions -- Conventional Case Problem: Y = a 0 X 1 a1 X 2 a2 c(X) =  p i X i Note: Linearity of Input Cost Function - typically assumed by economists - in general, not valid prices rise with demand wholesale, volume discounts Solution:[a 1 / X 1 *] Y / p 1 = [a 2 / X 2 *] Y / p 2 ==> [a 1 / X 1 *] p 1 = [a 2 / X 2 *] / p 2 ( * denotes an optimum value)

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 10 of 25 Optimality Conditions: Example Assume Y = 2X X (increasing RTS) c(X) = 5X 1 + 3X 2 Apply Conditions: = MP i / MC i [a 1 / X 1 *] / p 1 = [a 2 / X 2 *] / p 2 [0.48 /5] / X 1 * = [ 0.72/ 3] / X 2 * 9.6 / X 1 * = 24 / X 2 * This can be solved for a general relationship between resources => Expansion Path

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 11 of 25 Expansion Path l Locus of all optimal designs X* l Not a property of technical system alone l Depends on local prices l Optimal designs do not, in general, maintain constant ratios between optimal X i * Compare: crew of 20,000 ton ship crew of 200,000 ton ship larger ship does not need 10 times as many sailors as smaller ship

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 12 of 25 Expansion Path: Non-Linear Prices l Assume:Y = 2X X (increasing RTS) c(X) = X 1 + X (increasing costs) l Optimality Conditions: (0.48 / X 1 ) Y / 1 = (0.72 / X 2 ) Y / (1.5X ) => X 1 * = (X 2 *) 1.5 l Graphically: X2X2 Y X1X1 Expansion Path

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 13 of 25 Cost Functions: Concept l Not same as input cost function It represents the optimal cost of Y Not the cost of any set of X l C(Y) = C(X*) = f (Y) l It is obtained by inserting optimal values of resources (defined by expansion path) into input cost and production functions to give “best cost for any output”

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 14 of 25 Cost Functions: Graphical View l Graphically: l Great practical use: How much Y for budget?  Y for  B? Cost effectiveness,  B /  Y C(Y) Y Feasible Y C(Y) Economist’s view Engineer’s view Cost-Effectiveness

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 15 of 25 Cost Function Calculation: Linear Costs Cobb-Douglas Prod. Fcn: Y = a 0  X i a i Linear input cost function: c(X) =  p i X i l Result C(Y) = A(  p i a i / r )Y 1/r where r =  a i l Easy to estimate statistically => Solution for ‘a i ’ => Estimate of prod. fcn. Y = a 0  X i a i

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 16 of 25 Cost Function Calculation: Example l Assume Again: Y = 2X X c(X) = X 1 + X l Expansion Path:X 1 * = (X 2 *) 1.5 l Thus: Y = 2(X 2 *) 1.44 c(X*) = 2(X 2 *) 1.5 => X 2 * = (Y/2) 0.7 c(Y) = c(X*) = ( )Y 1.05

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 17 of 25 Real Example: Communications Satellites l System Design for Satellites at various altitudes and configurations l Source: O. de Weck and MIT co-workers l Data generated by a technical model that costs out wide variety of possible designs l Establishes a Cost Function l Note that we cannot in general expand along cost frontier. Technology limits what we can do: Only certain pathways are available

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 18 of 25 Key Parameters l Each star in the Trade Space corresponds to a vector:  r: altitude of the satellites  : minimum acceptable elevation angle  C: constellation type  Pt: maximal transmitter power  DA: Antenna diameter  f c : bandwidth  ISL: intersatellite links  T sat : Satellites lifetime l Some are fixed:  C: polar  f c : 40 kHz

Trade Space

Path example Constants: Pt=200 W DA=1.5 m ISL= Yes T sat = 5 r= 2000 km  = 5 deg N sats =24 Lifecycle cost [B$] System Lifetime capacity [min] r= 800 km  = 5 deg N sats =24 r= 400 km  = 5 deg N sats =112 r= 400 km  = 20 deg N sats =416 r= 400 km  = 35 deg N sats =1215

Tree example Constants: Pt=200 W DA=1.5 m ISL= Yes T sat = 5 r= 2000 km  = 5 deg N=24 e = 20 deg e = 35 deg r= 400 km  = 35 deg N= 1215 Lifecycle cost [B$] System Lifetime capacity [min]

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 22 of 25 Economies of Scale: Concept l A possible characteristic of cost function l Concept similar to returns to scale, except  ratio of ‘X i ’ not constant  refers to costs (economies) not “returns”  Not universal (as RTS) but depends on local costs l Economies of scale exist if costs increase slower than product Total cost = C(Y) = Y   < 1.0

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 23 of 25 Economies of Scale: Specific Cases If Cobb-Douglas, linear input costs, Increasing RTS (r =  a i > 1.0 => Economies of scale Optimality Conditions: [a 1 /X 1 *] / p 1 = [a 2 /X 2 *] / p 2 Thus: Inputs Cost is a function of X 1 * Also: Output is a function of [X 1 * ] r So: X 1 * is a function of Y 1/r Finally: C(Y) = function of [ Y 1/r ]

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 24 of 25 Economies of Scale: General Case Not necessarily true in general that Returns to scale => Economies of Scale Increasing costs may counteract advantages of returns to scale See example!! c(Y) = c(X*) = ( )Y 1.05 Contrarily, if unit prices decrease with volume (quite common) we can have Economies of Scale, without Returns to Scale

Engineering Systems Analysis for Design Richard de Neufville © Massachusetts Institute of Technology Marginal AnalysisSlide 25 of 25 Marginal Analysis: Summary l Assumptions convex feasible region -- Unconstrained l Optimality Criteria  MC/MP same for all inputs l Expansion path -- Locus of Optimal Design l Cost function -- cost along Expansion Path l Economies of scale (vs Returns to Scale) -- Exist if Cost/Unit decreases with volume