We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets?

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 8 Welfare Economics and The Gains From Trade
Advertisements

The Efficiency of Markets and the Costs of Taxation
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Welfare Economics Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers.
Welfare economics Recall, the allocation of resources refers to:
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics
Welfare Analysis. Ranking Economic systems  Objective: to find a criteria that allows us to rank different systems or allocations of resources.  This.
Chapter 7, Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
Principles of Microeconomics & Principles of Macroeconomics: Ch.7 First Canadian Edition Overview u Welfare Economics u Consumer Surplus u Producer Surplus.
Principles of Microeconomics
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
© 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets E conomics P R.
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets Outline:  Positive economics: Allocation of scarce resources using forces of demand and supply  Normative.
Chapter Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets 7.
LECTURE #6: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 7
Chapter Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets 7.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Consumers, Producers and the Efficiency of Markets Revisiting the Market Equilibrium –Do the equilibrium price and quantity.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
Consumer and Producer Surplus: Effects of Taxation
© 2011 Thomson South-Western. Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well- being.Welfare economics is the.
Market Equilibrium in Perfect Competition What do buyers and sellers get out of the market? And Why do economists think this is efficient?
Consumer and Producer Surplus AP Economics Mr. Bordelon.
Harcourt Brace & Company Chapter 7 Consumers, Producers and the Efficiency of Markets.
Welfare Economics Consumer and Producer Surplus. Consumer Surplus How much are you willing to pay for a pair of jeans? As an individual consumer, you.
Welfare economicsslide 1 Analysis of Competitive Markets In this section, we examine the social welfare implications of competitive markets. The approach.
Unit IV Consumer / Producer Surplus (Chapter 4) In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:  What is consumer surplus? How is it related.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Facoltà di Giurisprudenza MacerataEconomics Sara Lombardi.
Chapter 7 notes.
Willingness to Pay, MB and Consumer Surplus
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
CONSUMER SURPLUS, PRODUCER SURPLUS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Lecture PowerPoint® Slides to accompany 1. Chapter 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets 2 Copyright © 2011 Nelson Education Limited.
Principles of Micro Chapter 7: “Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets” by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
A rational decision maker makes choices so as best to achieve a clear goal. Rational behavior most often requires marginal analysis in which the marginal.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets Chapter 7 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies.
ECON 101: Introduction to Economics - I Lecture 3 – Demand and Supply.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
Welfare Economics Chapter 7. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: What is consumer surplus? How is it related to the demand curve?
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets Chapter 7 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies.
Principles of Economics Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets 7. Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency.
Elasticity of Demand Chapter 5. Slope of Demand Curves Demand curves do not all have the same slope Slope indicates response of buyers to a change in.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets Chapter 7.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 1 © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned,
1 Economics 110 Introduction to Economic Theory Professor Tanya Rosenblat Perfectly Competitive Markets.
Consumer’s and Producer’s Surplus Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 3
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Revisiting the Market Equilibrium Do the equilibrium price and quantity maximize.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Welfare Economics Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
0 Quick Review!  What is welfare economics? Measures how the allocation of resources affects economic well being  How do we measure this? Consumer &
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning Application: The Costs of Taxation Recall that welfare economicsRecall that welfare economics is the study.
MACROECONOMICS Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets CHAPTER SEVEN 1.
Economic Analysis for Business Session IX: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus and Market Efficiency-1 Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
© 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets E conomics P R.
Economics 2010 Lecture 9 Markets and efficiency. Competition and Efficiency  The Key Question  Allocative Efficiency  The Invisible Hand  Obstacles.
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
N. G R E G O R Y M A N K I W Premium PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich 2008 update © 2008 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 6-1 CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all.
EFFICIENCY by Caterina Ficiarà. We know that a society has to face different problems. To sum up, the main difficulties we can find in every nation are:
Market Equilibrium Week 3.  At the market equilibrium price: ◦ Quantity demanded by consumers = quantity supplied by firms/producers/sellers ◦ Without.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Welfare Economics Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers.
ECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells with Margaret Ray and David Anderson SECOND EDITION in MODULES.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Producer Surplus >> ©2011  Worth Publishers.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Presentation transcript:

We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets? Do competitive markets provide the “right” quantity? What about price? (Of course, buyers always want a lower price; sellers always want a higher price.) Is there a “right” price?

These questions bring us to the topic of Welfare economics: The study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Both buyers and sellers benefit from their participation in the market. (Remember “basic principle #5”!) We will need to develop tools for measuring, in dollar terms, buyers’ and sellers’ benefits from market participation. “consumer and producer surplus”

Willingness to pay (WTP): The maximum amount that a consumer will pay for a particular unit of a good. For a given consumer, WTP varies among units of a good (higher WTP for first unit than for second, etc.). WTP also varies across consumers (some have “high” WTP; some “low” WTP). WTP is a measure, in dollar terms, of the value to the consumer of that unit of the good.

Consumer surplus: A consumer’s willingness to pay minus the amount the consumer actually pays = “value” to consumer minus amount paid. Consumer surplus and demand curves? An example: The market for gizmos. Assume:... people differ in their WTP for the first gizmo of the day,... but everyone has zero WTP for the second, third, fourth, etc. gizmo each day. (Gizmos are nice to have, but nobody needs more than one per day!)

Suppose there are five consumers who differ in their WTP for a gizmo:

The market demand curve for gizmos: Start off with price above $1.00/gizmo, and gradually reduce price. ($/gizmo) (gizmos/day) As price falls below 1.00, Al’s demand “kicks in.” As price falls below 0.80, Betty’s demand “kicks in.” And so on... quantity demanded increases by 1 as each level of WTP is reached.

($/gizmo) (gizmos/day) Here’s that demand curve again: 0.60 Suppose that the price of a gizmo is $0.60/gizmo. 3 Quantity demanded is 3 gizmos/day. (Al, Betty, and Carl demand; Doug and Emily don’t.) Al’s C.S. = WTP - p = = Betty’s C.S. = = Carl’s C.S. = = Total C.S. ($0.70/day) = area below demand, above mkt. price.

Now in terms of a more “conventional” demand curve: ($/unit) (units/day) Demand Q1Q1... and quantity purchased and consumed at Q consumer surplus is the (shaded) area below the demand curve and above market price, over the range of quantity purchased and consumed. p 1 With price at the level p 1...

One more thing to notice from this construction of demand: The demand price at any quantity measures the willingness to pay (“value”) for the marginal consumer (the first consumer who would leave the market if price were to increase). For this reason, the demand curve is sometimes described as a graph of “marginal value.”

Consumer surplus gives a measure (in dollar terms) of buyers’ benefits from market participation. What about sellers? Opportunity cost: The value of what must be given up to produce a particular unit of the good. As such, opportunity cost is the minimum amount that a seller would be willing to accept for that unit.

For a given seller, opportunity cost can vary across units of a good. Opportunity cost can also vary across sellers (some might be “high” cost sellers; others “low” cost sellers.) Producer surplus: The amount a seller is paid for a good minus the seller’s opportunity cost of producing it.

Producer surplus and supply curves? Gizmos again. Assume:... suppliers differ in their opportunity cost of the first gizmo produced per day.... but all producers have infinite opportunity cost for the second, third, etc. gizmo each day. (It’s impossible to produce more than one gizmo per day.)

Suppose there are five suppliers who differ in their opportunity cost of a gizmo:

The market supply curve for gizmos: Start off with price at zero and gradually increase it. ($/gizmo) (gizmos/day) As price rises above 0.25, Arliss’ supply “kicks in.” As price rises above 0.50, Bob’s supply “kicks in.” And so on... quantity supplied increase by 1 as each level of opportunity cost is reached.

Here’s that supply curve again: ($/gizmo) (gizmos/day) Quantity supplied is 3 gizmos/day. (Arliss, Bob, and Cindy supply; Denise and Edgar don’t.) Arliss’ P.S. = p - opp. cost = = 0.50 Suppose that the price of a gizmo is $0.75/gizmo.) 0.75 Bob’s P.S. = = 0.25 Cindy’s P.S. = = 0.05 Total P.S. ($0.80/day) = area above supply, below mkt. price.

Now in terms of a more “conventional” supply curve: ($/unit) (units/day) Supply Q 1... and quantity produced and sold at Q producer surplus is the (shaded) area above the supply curve and below market price, over the range of quantity produced and sold. p1p1 With price at the level of p 1...

One more thing to notice from this construction of supply: The supply price at any quantity measures the opportunity cost for the marginal producer (the first producer who would leave the market if price were to decrease). For this reason, it’s legitimate to think of the supply curve as a graph of “marginal cost.”

Consumer and producer surplus measure, in dollar terms, consumers’ and producers’ benefits from market participation. Consumer surplus measures an implicit benefit -- it doesn’t really show up as dollars in our pocket. Instead, it’s the difference between the maximum amount we would have willingly paid, for all units purchased, and the amount we actually do pay. Producer surplus is more explicit -- it’s closely related to the concept of “profit.” (More later.)

Consumer surplus = Value to buyers - Amount paid by buyers Producer surplus = Amount received by sellers - Cost to sellers Total surplus = Consumer surplus + Producer surplus = Value to buyers - Cost to sellers If total surplus is maximized, we say that “efficiency” is achieved.

Some conditions for efficiency: The total quantity of goods supplied must be allocated to the buyers who value them most highly. (Otherwise, total value to buyers could be increased by a transfer from one buyer to another.) The total quantity of goods demanded must be allocated to sellers who can produce them at least cost. (Otherwise, total cost to sellers could be decreased by a transfer from one seller to another.)

Let’s see if these conditions are met in competitive market equilibrium. The “price rationing” mechanism of competitive markets achieves these conditions. Only buyers who value the good higher than p* will buy. ($/unit) (units/day) Demand Supply p* Q* E (those on AE) A Only sellers whose cost is lower than p* will sell. (those on CE) C Rationing by price achieves the “right” allocations on both sides of the market.

There’s one more condition that must be satisfied for efficiency (maximization of total surplus): We must have production, trade, and consumption of all units for which marginal value exceeds marginal cost (all units for which WTP of the marginal buyer exceeds opportunity cost of the marginal seller) so that all potential gains from trade will be realized.

Is this condition achieved in competitive equilibrium? At output Q 1 (less than Q*), marginal value... Q1Q1 marginal value marginal cost... exceeds marginal cost. Q2Q2 At output Q 2 (greater than Q*), marginal value... marginal value marginal cost...is less than marginal cost. Efficiency requires trade of all units up to Q*... none beyond. The equilibrium quantity is the “right” quantity in this sense. ($/unit) (units/day) Demand Supply p* Q*

So in competitive market equilibrium, efficiency is achieved (total surplus is maximized). The “right” quantity of output is produced, traded, and consumed and it’s allocated (by the price rationing mechanism) in the “right” way. (Buyers with the highest values buy. Sellers with the lowest costs sell.) Remember basic principle #6: “Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity”?

One very (!) important caveat to all of this: Efficiency -- maximization of total surplus -- has to do with the size of the “pie.” We can (and should!) still worry about how the pie is divided among society’s members. These are “equity” issues.