Convergence and Divergence in Growth Regressions Michele Battisti University of Palermo Gianfranco di Vaio Cassa Depositi e Prestiti Joseph Zeira Hebrew.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
International Trade and Development. Lecture Outline (1)What do we include in a Growth model? (2)Evidence of the relationship between increased trade.
Advertisements

Autocorrelation Functions and ARIMA Modelling
Multiple Regression.
Introduction Describe what panel data is and the reasons for using it in this format Assess the importance of fixed and random effects Examine the Hausman.
Regression Analysis.
Dynamic panels and unit roots
Innovation and Competitiveness Jan Fagerberg, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo (based on joint work with Mark Knell and.
Endogenous growth theory
PSME M1 Economic Growth Tutorial.  Introduction ◦ Review of Classic Solow Model ◦ Shortfalls of Solow ◦ Human Capital Accumulation ◦ Convergence Theory.
0 Productivity Growth and Convergence in Vietnamese Agriculture Wendi Sun Rockland Trust Company March 25 th, 2015.
Quality of government and the returns of European regional policies Andrés Rodríguez-Pose, LSE with Jose Enrique Garcilazo, OECD Università di Bologna.
By Matthew Higgins and Jeffrey G. Williamson
Openness, Economic Growth, and Human Development: Evidence from South Asian countries from Middlesex University Department of Economics and.
Economic Growth: The Solow Model
Chapter 17 Unemployment, Inflation, and Growth. 2 Introduction In Chapter 4, 5, 6, we have studied a classical model of the complete economy, but said.
Chapter 11: Saving, Capital Accumulation, and Output Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Macroeconomics, 5/e Olivier Blanchard.
On the Evolution of the World Income by Charles I. Jones.
Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 The Theory of Economic Growth.
Agricultural Productivity and Economic Growth: Empirical Analysis on the Contemporary Developing Countries.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow.
Long-Run Economic Growth
Innovation Economics Class 3.
Why Has Income Inequality in Thailand Increased? An Analysis Using Surveys.
Technological Progress
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
What affects MFP in the long-run? Evidence from Canadian industries Danny Leung and Yi Zheng Bank of Canada, Research Department Structural Studies May.
[ 1 ] MIGRATION AND PRODUCTIVITY. LESSONS FROM THE UK-SPAIN EXPERIENCES This project is funded by the European Commission, Research Directorate General.
Income convergence prospects in Europe: Assessing the role of human capital dynamics Jesus Crespo Cuaresma Miroslava Luchava Havettová Martin Lábaj BRATISLAVA.
Globalization, Creative Destruction, and Labor Share Change: Evidence on the Determinants and Mechanisms from Longitudinal Plant-level Data Petri Böckerman.
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 11 The Theory of Economic Growth.
Company LOGO New Paradigm for International Insurance Comparison: With an Application to Comparison of Seven Insurance Markets Wei Zheng, Peking University.
Infrastructure and Long Run Economic Growth David Canning Infrastructure and Growth: Theory, Empirical Evidence and policy Lessons Cape Town May.
Spatial and non spatial approaches to agricultural convergence in Europe Luciano Gutierrez*, Maria Sassi** *University of Sassari **University of Pavia.
Contribution of Education and Training to Innovation and Growth
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
Chapter 3 Growth and Accumulation Item Etc. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Macroeconomics, 10e © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Catching up and global (asymmetric) interdependence ECLAC Summer School 2013.
Income Benchmark Applied Inclusive Growth Analytics Course June 29, 2009 Leonardo Garrido.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS AND GROWTH: THE GENERAL SOLOW MODEL Chapter 5 – second lecture Introducing Advanced Macroeconomics:
1 REGRESSION ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA: INTRODUCTION A panel data set, or longitudinal data set, is one where there are repeated observations on the same.
Seðlabanki Íslands Inflation control around the world: Why are some countries more successful than others? Thórarinn G. Pétursson Central Bank of Iceland.
National Institute of Economic and Social Research WP8: Methodological Issues in Development Scenarios for Health Expenditures for EU Ehsan Khoman and.
Discussion of time series and panel models
Chapter 4.  “Second Generation” growth models  The role of human capital in economic growth  Determinants of technological progress  Externalities.
THE IMPACT OF INTERNATIONAL OUTSOURCING ON EMPLOYMENT: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EU COUNTRIES Martin Falk and Yvonne Wolfmayr Austrian Institute of Economic.
International Trade and Income Differences Michael E. Waugh.
17 October 2010 The Information Content of Capacity Utilisation Rates for Output Gap Estimates Michael Graff and Jan-Egbert Sturm.
Udviklingsøkonomi - grundfag Lecture 4 Convergence? 1.
Aid, policies and Growth
1 Prof. George E. Halkos & Epameinondas A. Paizanos The channels of the effect of government expenditure on the environment: evidence using dynamic methods.
Human Capital The exogenous growth model of Solow presents a number of unresolved questions: –The growth rate of the economy in the steady state is not.
PHYSICAL INVESTMENT, HEALTH INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC COMPETITIVENESS IN AFRICA By Abiodun O. Folawewo and Adeniyi Jimmy Adedokun Department of Economics,
International portfolio diversification benefits: Cross-country evidence from a local perspective Authors of the Paper: Joost Driessen Luc Laeven Presented.
Cross-border bank lending versus FDI in Africa’s growth story Jose Brambila Macias Isabella Massa Victor Murinde University of ReadingOverseas Development.
International portfolio diversification benefits: Cross-country evidence from a local perspective By J. Driessen and L. Laeven Presented by Michal Kolář,
The role of education in economic growth Evelyn Chew (66388) Le Hong Hanh (6112)
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
Advanced Macroeconomics:
Chapter 26 Economic growth
Luciano Gutierrez*, Maria Sassi**
Innovation and Competitiveness
Advanced Macroeconomics:
Productivity Growth and Convergence: Theory and Evidence
KRUGMAN’S Economics for AP® S E C O N D E D I T I O N.
GROWTH ECONOMICS and Fund-raising in international cooperation SECS-P01, CFU 9 Economics for Development academic year HUMAN CAPITAL MODELS.
Product moment correlation
Empirical Applications of Neoclassical Growth Models Chapter 3
Presentation transcript:

Convergence and Divergence in Growth Regressions Michele Battisti University of Palermo Gianfranco di Vaio Cassa Depositi e Prestiti Joseph Zeira Hebrew University of Jerusalem and LUISS Jerusalem, June 19, 2014

Introduction This paper extends the main model of growth regressions (Barro 1991 and later), in order to overcome a number of critiques on this literature. One main result of growth regressions is that the cross-country distribution of output converges to a limit distribution. But direct studies of this distribution (Bernard and Durlauf 1995 and more) found that it diverges over time. The choice of control variables for estimation of convergence is arbitrary and their total number already exceeds 150. Measures of the rate of convergence differ across studies.

Introduction: Main Results Our extended model of growth regression enables us to reconcile the conflicting results of convergence and divergence. We succeed in estimating the dynamic parameters of the model without use of any control variables. We provide an explanation to different estimates of the rate of convergence. We can isolate the long-run effect of explanatory variables, which cannot be done in standard growth regressions.

Introduction: Our Extension The standard growth regression model assumes that the ratio between output per worker of a country and its productivity (TFP) converges at an annual rate b to a constant number. We add an assumption on how productivity evolves over time: it converges to a long-run path at a rate c. This long-run path follows the global technology (or productivity) frontier. But it may follow it only partially. We assume that each country has a parameter d that measures by how much it follows the global frontier in the long-run. If d = 1 it follows fully, and if d < 1, it follows partially.

Introduction: Justification and Implications Our approach can be described as growth in small open economies. Most countries do not invent new technologies, but use the innovations created elsewhere. They can either adopt an innovation, or not. Hence, d might be smaller than 1. The model implies that growth is characterized by 3 parameters: b measures convergence of output, c measures convergence of productivity, and d measures divergence from the frontier. We estimate the 3 parameters and find that d is below 1 for many countries (the global average is 0.7).

The Growth Regressions Model We present our contribution by embedding it within the canonical Growth Regression Model, as presented in the survey of Durlauf, Johnson and Temple (2005). Output is described by: The labor force grows at a rate n(j) and productivity grows at a rate g(j): Most studies assume that g is common to all countries.

The Convergence Assumption Output per worker: Efficiency Output per worker: It is assumed that efficiency output per worker adjusts gradually to its long-run value: The gradual adjustment can be due to bounded savings in a closed economy, as in the Solow model, or if the economy is open, due to costly adjustment of capital, as in this paper. The parameter b(j) is the rate of convergence.

Cross-Country Growth Regressions From the convergence equation we can derive the common two forms of growth regressions. The first is a cross-section regression, where the rate of growth is over a long period: Initial productivity and its rate of growth are not observed. They are controlled for by various explanatory variables. As a result this estimation cannot differentiate between a level effect and a rate of growth effect of an explanatory variable.

Panel Growth Regressions The accumulation of data in recent years enables us to use panel growth regressions, thus adding more observations. The basic panel equation is derived from the convergence assumption above: The estimation of panels creates problems as well. The main one is that while there is high variability in output and in productivity, there is not much variability in the explanatory variables, like geography, ethnic composition, institutions, fiscal policy, education, etc.

Extending the Model We extend the growth regression model by assuming that instead of growing at a fixed rate g(j), the country’s productivity converges to a path that follows the global frontier, but not necessarily fully. The global frontier: Productivity of a country satisfies: The rate of following the frontier satisfies:

Implications: Output Convergence The basic growth regression model implies: Hence, output should be cointegrated with productivity (TFP). The coefficient of integration should be The error correction coefficient should be b(j), the output rate of convergence. According to our open economy model:

Implications: Productivity Convergence and Divergence The extension to the growth regression model implies: Hence, productivity should be cointegrated with the global frontier, where the coefficient of cointegration is d(j). The error correction coefficient should be c(j), the productivity rate of convergence. Note that productivity might converge to its long-run path, but at the same time diverge from the frontier, if d(j) < 1.

Implications: Output Convergence and Divergence in the Extended Model Hence, output is cointegrated with the global frontier, where the coefficient of cointegration is. The error correction mechanism is a combination of b and c. Hence, output converges to a long-run path, but it can diverge from the global frontier and from the countries at the frontier. This reconciles the findings of growth regressions and of divergence of the distribution of output across countries.

Implications: Differences If we take differences of the extended growth regression model we get: Hence, this enables us an alternative estimation of the parameters b, c and d for each country. Note that this estimation does not require control variables.

Implications: Varying Rate of Convergence I According to the extended model, the standard growth regression is: But output and productivity in period 0 are correlated. Hence it does not estimate b but a combination of b and c.

Implications: Varying Rate of Convergence II Assume that the regression coefficient of on output is R. Then the estimated rate of convergence is described by: This coefficient therefore varies by t. If t = 1: If we average growth over a long period the estimate is closer to b (if c > b, which we show below).

Data We use data on output per capita, which is PPP adjusted, from the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (2013). Specifically, real GDP per capita, in PPP adjusted Geary- Khamis 1990 US$, for 139 countries over the years We remove a few outliers (like oil producing countries) and are left with 124 countries. For a set of 30 countries the data are from 1870 to For the global frontier we use as a proxy the US output per capita. The US has a stable growth rate over the period and is the leading among large countries.

US GDP per Capita

Ln of GDP per Capita in Regions and in the US

An Example of an Outlier

Panel Cointegration of Output and TFP: CoefficientWhole Sample b0.0105* (0.007) 1/(1-α)1.669*** (0.404) Countries72

Panel Cointegration of TFP and Global Frontier: CoefficientWhole Sample c0.0734*** (0.006) d0.3401** (0.155) Countries72

Panel Cointegration of Output and the Global Frontier: CoefficientWhole SampleWithout Oil & Outliers Error Correction0.0389*** (0.002) *** (0.002) d0.688*** (0.093) 0.708** (0.072) Test for d = 1 χ 2 =23.95 P=0.00 χ 2 =16.63 P=0.00 Hausman Test for Heterogeneity χ 2 =2.80 P=0.094 χ 2 =9.23 P=0.002 No. of Countries Standard errors in parenthesis. 2. Hausman null hypothesis: difference in coefficient not systematic.

Divergence by Regions CoefficientOECDSSALACSEAOther Countries Error Correction *** (0.006) *** (0.005) *** (0.004) *** (0.006) *** (0.007) d1.060*** (0.078) 0.201* (0.115) 0.634** (0.098) 1.617*** (0.322) 0.623*** (0.177) Test for d = 1 χ 2 =0.59 P= χ 2 =48.54 P=0.000 χ 2 =14.05 P=0.000 χ 2 =3.67 P=0.056 χ 2 =4.31 P=0.038 Hausman Test for Heterogeneity χ 2 =0.54 P=0.464 χ 2 =1.18 P=0.277 χ 2 =7.33 P=0.007 χ 2 = P= χ 2 =9.71 P=0.002 No. of Countries

Convergence and Divergence In all regressions countries follow what is called β- convergence, or conditional convergence. But here this is interpreted as convergence to own long-run growth path. But the long-run path may converge to the frontier or diverge from it, depending on whether d = 1 or smaller than 1. We show that for most countries d < 1, so that most countries diverge from the frontier. This fits the many findings on divergence.

Panel Cointegration Results for 30 Countries in the years ParameterCoefficientzP>zTest d = 1Hausmann Test for Heterogeneity Error Correction (0.004) d0.993 (0.060) χ 2 (1)=0.01 P>χ 2 (1): χ 2 (2)=2.86 P> χ 2 (2): 0.091

Effect of Explanatory Variables on d Next we estimate the effect of various explanatory variables on the estimated d. Previous growth regressions could estimate whether an explanatory variable affects output. The effects of these same explanatory variables on d can identify their long-run effect. We compare this estimation with a standard growth regression to check whether these long-run effect actually differ from the overall effect.

The Explanatory Variables I TROPIC is the share of land in a country that is tropical. COAST is the share of land in a country that is within 100 km from a coast or from a navigable river. ETHNIC is the measure of ethnic fractionalization in a country. Y_50 is the natural logarithm of the GDP per capita at EDU is the average years of schooling of people above age 15 during the time of the panel.

The Explanatory Variables II OPEN measures openness by trade policy over the years A country is closed (i) if average tariff rate exceeded 40%; (ii) if non-tariff barriers covered more than 40% of imports; (iii) if it had a socialist economic system; (iv) if it had a state monopoly of major exports; or (v) if black-market premium exceeded 20% during the 1970s or the 1980s. ICRG is average measure of quality of institutions during (International Country Risk Guide). G/Y is the share of public expenditures in GDP, averaged over the years

Explanatory Variables: Corr. Matrix TROPICSCOASTETHNICY_50EDUOPENG/Y TROPICS COAST ETHNIC Y_ EDU OPEN G/Y ICRG

Taking Out SEA and OECD In the following regressions we estimate the effects of these explanatory variables (except for ICRG, for insignificance) for all countries and then without South East Asia and even without the OECD countries. Some of the South East Asian countries are in the midst of a period of catching up with the frontier so their rate of growth is very high and they appear to have d that is much higher than 1. We know that this catching up will stop some time, but the data do not know. The OECD countries have d = 1, which is the maximum d. Hence they are at a corner solution, so that d is less sensitive to the various explanatory variables.

A Standard Growth Regression Dependent Variable: AVG Explanatory Variable(1) Whole sample (2) Without SEA (3) Without SEA and OECD TROPIC *** (0.235) *** (0.242) *** (0.281) COAST0.008 *** (0.003) *** (0.003) ** (0.004) Y_ *** (0.178) *** (0.194) *** (0.222) ETHNIC * (0.452) (0.422) (0.574) EDU0.149 *** (0.059) ** (0.060) ** (0.076) OPEN1.109 *** (0.231) *** (0.234) *** (0.471) G/Y *** (0.898) ** (0.859) ** (0.986) CONST *** (1.267) *** (1.343) *** (1.566) R2R OBS

Effect on d Dependent Variable: d Explanatory Variable(1) Whole sample (2) Without SEA (3) Without SEA and OECD TROPIC ** (0.152) *** (0.133) *** (0.144) COAST0.004 ** (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Y_ *** (0.127) ** (0.122) * (0.137) ETHNIC * (0.282) ** (0.218) ** (0.304) EDU0.088 ** (0.039) (0.038) (0.043) OPEN0.591 *** (.150) ** (0.150) *** (0.291) G/Y ** (0.578) (0.513) (.680) CONST *** (0.946) *** (0.835) *** (0.966) R2R OBS

Results The effects of explanatory variables in the standard cross- country growth regression are very different from the effects on d. Education has a positive and significant effect on growth, but not on d. The size of the public sector has a significant negative effect on output in growth regression, but its effect on d is insignificant. The effect of ethnic fractionalization on output is insignificant, but its effect on long-run growth is negative and significant.

Conclusions It is still a bit too early to throw growth regressions into the dump. Including the global frontier and productivity can enrich the estimation of convergence and divergence of countries. We reconcile the results of growth regressions with alternative measures of convergence and divergence. We also estimate convergence without control variables. We also improve the estimation of the rate of convergence. This approach also enables us to better evaluate various explanations to growth, by isolating the long-run effect.

Robustness Checks 1 Annual data b0.091 *** (0.007) *** (0.007) *** (0.006) *** (0.006) d0.494 *** (0.096) *** (0.094) *** (0.090) *** (0.099) Test d = 1  2 =28.01 (0.000)  2 =24.48 (0.000)  2 =20.17 (0.000)  2 =18.86 (0.000)

Robustness Checks 2 3 years averaged data b0.058 *** (0.004) *** (0.004) *** (0.003) *** (0.003) d0.616 *** (0.079) *** (0.073) *** (0.073) *** (0.073) Test d = 1  2 =23.99 (0.000)  2 =23.03 (0.000)  2 =20.71 (0.000)  2 =18.65 (0.000)

Robustness Checks 3 5 years averaged data b0.045 *** (0.003) *** (0.003) *** (0.003) *** (0.002) d0.634 *** (0.100) *** (0.099) *** (0.072) *** (0.072) Test d = 1  2 =13.35 (0.000)  2 =9.82 (0.002)  2 =19.92 (0.000)  2 =16.63 (0.000)

Robustness Checks 4 10 years averaged data b0.031 *** (0.003) *** (0.020) d0.686 *** (0.135) *** (0.078) Test d = 1  2 =5.36 (0.021)  2 =14.76 (0.000) Observations124

Robustness Checks 5: Changes in d

Robustness Checks 6: y without human capital ParameterTotal SampleOECDLACSSASEAOther Error correction0.04 (0.002) (0.006) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.003) z P>z d0.367 (0.102) (0.089) 0.12 (0.131) (0.234) (0.256) (0.21) z p>z Number of countries