Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byBrook Norman Modified over 8 years ago
1
C OST OF CAPITAL OF PROJECTS
2
Project cost of capital from CAPM Applying the CAPM to estimate the cost of capital of projects Recall: the cost of capital is the expected return on a capital market investment opportunity having the same risk as the project Recall: opportunity cost: this capital market expected return is forgone if I invest in the project Recall: only relevant risk matters, which is measured by beta in the CAPM Let’s look at the estimation of the parameters of the CAPM!
3
Risk-free rate Look for an asset which has no risk… As low default risk as possible: government bonds with the best rating But: such yields are usually fixed (riskless) in nominal terms → inflation risk Take inflation-indexed (inflation-protected) government bonds About risk in reinvesting the interest payments: take zero-coupon bonds What maturity? – Matching that of the project Typical value: 1-3% p.a., in real terms
4
Average market risk premium Risk premium for β = 1, that is, E(r M ) – r f Taking a global approach – diversification globally is reasonable Approximation of a global market portfolio: a global stock market index, e.g., MSCI ACWI Estimation: from historical data It is assumed, necessarily, that the expectation about the average market risk premium is stable over time Thus, take the average of the past differences between the returns: Typical value: 5-6% p.a., in real terms
5
Project beta Recall: slope of the security characteristic line, resulting from a linear regression between returns Problem: market portfolio returns are indeed observable, but there are no data on project returns Projects are not traded (publicly) → no price data → no return data Estimation compromise: take something „comparable”: industry betas Industry betas from stocks of many firms in a given industry Take the beta of an industry the project activities mostly correspond to (if not so clear, may even take weighted average of several industry betas) Look at some examples…
6
Country risk Risks associated with the country the project is undertaken in (e.g., political) Question: is it diversifiable? (i.e., completely idiosyncratic) If intended to be taken into account, in the cost of capital: where r crp is calculated based on, e.g., credit ratings of government bonds
7
F INANCIAL CALCULATIONS
8
Common cash flow patterns (I.) Annuity: What is the present value of an annuity of A = 100 lasting for 15 periods, if the discount rate is 12%? (681) How long should an annuity of A = 50 be in order for its present value to be at least 100, if the discount rate is 18%? (2.7 ~ 3) Which option would you prefer: $10,000 today or $1,000 each year for 15 years, if the discount rate is 10%? (first > $7,606) At least how much should the amount A of an annuity lasting for 10 periods be in order for the present value of the annuity to be at least 80, if the discount rate is 15%? (16)
9
Common cash flow patterns (II.) Perpetuity: What is the present value of a perpetuity of A = 100, if the discount rate is 20%? (500) How much should the annual amount A of a perpetuity be in order for its present value to be at least 250, if the discount rate is 15%? (37.5) What discount rate makes the present value of a perpetuity of A = 25 equal to 100? (25%)
10
Common cash flow patterns (III.) Growing annuity: Growing perpetuity:
11
Common cash flow patterns (IV.) Growing annuity & perpetuity calculations: Assume that g = 3% and r = 10% What is the present value if F 1 = 100 and the series lasts for 5 periods? (400) How much should F 1 be in order for the present value to be 320? (g.a.: 80; g.p.: 22.4) If F 1 = 100, at least how many periods should the series last for in order for the present value to be larger than 500? (6.55 ~ 7) Run the same, but for g = 10% (455; 70.4; 5.5 ~ 6) The pattern is a growing perpetuity. If F 1 = 100 and r = 10%, then what g, or if g = 3%, then what r makes the present value equal to 1250? (g = 2%; r = 11%)
12
NPV and IRR We have discussed the formulas and the decision rules… Issues related to the IRR Multiple roots „Double relativity” – ranking mutually exclusive projects with different initial investment and/or life Project Cash flow ($)IRR (%) NPV r=10% F0F0 F1F1 A-10,000+20,000100+8,182 B-20,000+35,00075+11,818 Cash flow ($) IRR (%) NPV r=10% ProjectF0F0 F1F1 F2F2 F3F3 F4F4 F5F5 etc. C-9,0006,0005,0004,00000 333,592 D-9,0001,800 …209,000
13
Profitability index (PI) (I.) Case of scarce capacity allocation General formulation: Capital rationing: Formulation may also be for PV instead of NPV Then: decision criterion: PI > 1 Note that PI is relative with respect to initial investment → problem when comparing projects with different initial investment
14
Profitability index (PI) (II.) Example: consider the following projects: Ranking according to PI: D > B > C > A > E Assume that the capital constraint is 150 – then D, B, A projects would be undertaken Because F 0 altogether is 80 + 20 + 50 = 150 After D and B, insufficient allotment remains for C E is by no means to be undertaken, because PI E < 1 (NPV E < 0) F0F0 PVPI A-50601,20 B-20301,50 C-1101501,36 D-802102,63 E-70500,71
15
Profitability index (PI) (III.) Run the same, but for a constraint of 200 Then, by following the same logic, again D, B, A projects would be undertaken, total NPV is 150 in this case But take a more careful look: what if D and C were undertaken? Total F 0 = 80 + 110 = 190 < 200 Total NPV = 130 + 40 = 170 > 150 ! And we are interested in total NPV, that is to be maximized Explanation for the issue: PI is relative – not only the specific benefit matters, but the amount of unspent dollars also (cf. backpack problem…)
16
Annual equivalent (AE) (I.) For comparing mutually exclusive and recurring projects with unequal lives Their annual cash flow equivalents are compared It is assumed that the projects will be undertaken repeatedly with the same conditions, until a common finite cessation point or infinity A level annual amount is sought the NPV of the annuity of which equals the NPV of the project within the “cycle” In essence, the cash flow pattern of the project is “flattened” in this approach
17
Annual equivalent (AE) (II.) Illustration: We can choose from two types of air-conditioners to be installed in our office. Type A can be purchased for $10,000 and operated annually for $1,500 with expected life-span of 7 years. Type B can be purchased for $14,000 and operated annually for $1,100 with expected life- span of 10 years. The discount rate is 9%. Which type should we choose, assuming that we would stick with the choice until infinity? (-$3,487 < -$3,281, so B)
18
F INANCING DECISIONS
19
Financing decisions Investment decisions: what to acquire? Financing decisions: from what kinds of sources? Thus far silently assumed: financing completely with equity Question: does it matter if financing not completely with equity? In other words: is it worth to employ some debt beside equity? Would shareholders be better off then?
20
Capital structure The proportions of equity (E) and debt (D) in financing D/E ratio – leverage Unlevered vs. levered firm Before-tax value (A BT ) and after-tax value (A) Value of corporate tax (T cE )
21
MM propositions Modigliani and Miller Capital structure does not matter in a perfect world… Proposition I.: The value of a firm does not depend on its capital structure; that is, the proportion of debt and equity financing is irrelevant to value. The value of a firm is determined by its real assets and not by its capital structure. Proposition II.: The cost of equity capital (E(r E )) and its relevant risk (β E ) of a firm both increase as the firm’s leverage (i.e., debt-equity ratio) increases. It would be good because calculations could be done assuming completely equity financing
22
Perfect, in terms of the CAPM (I.)
23
Perfect, in terms of the CAPM (II.) The weighted average cost of capital (A = D + E):
24
Imperfections We look at two cases of imperfections: Tax savings Interest on debt is (corporate) tax-deductible More debt → more interest → less tax to be paid This saving goes to shareholders – an argument pro debt financing Efficiency losses (costs of financial distress) Higher leverage increases costs, decreases efficiency E.g., customers, suppliers, employees, monitoring An argument contra debt financing But the combined effect can be regarded negligible…
25
Effect of tax savings
26
Effect of efficiency losses
27
Combined effect
28
Combined effect – implications If negligible: we are back to the MM propositions Even in an imperfect world, capital structure choice may be considered irrelevant For simplicity, it is then valid to do calculations assuming completely equity financing
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.