Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byDoris Davis Modified over 8 years ago
1
Quantifying Fisher Behavior Under Restrictions Hans van Oostenbrugge, Jeff Powell and Jos Smit
2
Introduction Indirectly Incorporate Fisher Behavior Nonlinear catch - input relationship Accepted theory in economics (decreasing returns to inputs) Seldom implemented in models of fishery management EU fishery management: TAC ----> Effort regulation Single species -----> Multi species Integration of economic activities into models
3
Fisher behaviour under TAC limitation F Effort
4
Fisher behavior under effort limitation F
5
Relationship Effort - F
6
Effort limit TAC limit
7
Objective of the study A simple and practical algorithm for short-run, Catch-Effort relationship Behavior based on economic motivation Appropriate for full feedback biological models Based on variation in results by vessel and by trip Applicable for other EU fleet segments
8
Fisher behaviour under effort limitation Fishers optimize Revenue / Effort by means of re-allocation of effort Spatial, where trips are taken Timing of trips Transfer between vessels Work through Q Nonlinear short-run relationship Effort and F Qt=q0*(Et/E0)^c
9
Data and methodology NL flatfish fishery Mixed fishery – 2 main target species (plaice/sole) 1 gear (large BTs), 1 fishing ground Transferability of effort between vessels Data Landings(value) by vessel by trip by rectangle 2001 - 2006 Cross sectional analysis ANOVA Estimating exponential relationship E and F
10
Results: fishing patterns Cumulative effortCumulative value landings
11
Modeling effects on forecasts IMARES- model Full feedback model Developed for evaluation flatfish management plan Dutch flatfish fishery (Plus UK and “other”) 2 species Sensitivity analysis to non-linearity in relationship f and F
12
Simulating effects: catchability +20%
13
Simulating effects: landings +3% +1%
14
Simulating effects: economics +1% +3%
15
Simulating effects: biology -20% -13%
16
Discussion Limitations of the approach Applies to effort reduction scenarios Short run – no investments Applicability to other fisheries: Theoretically to all management systems: fishermen: optimize Revenue / limiting input In practice only in specific fleet segments: flexible transfer of fishing rights logbook data available
17
Conclusions Nonlinearity in the relationship effort F is important Especially in transition from TAC to effort management Integration biological and economic models is essential for proper management
18
Future work Models for other types of management Further simplification: Can non-linear relationship between E and F be derived from variance of trip results?
19
Questions © Wageningen UR
20
R code to calculate effort beta. load("C:\\Documents and Settings\\J Powell\\Bureaublad\\EFIMAS.RData") ###Main idea: Sort Revenues per Unit Effort, Rank trips in decreasing order of value ###Order of trips will impact distribution of catch dat <- list(); dat <- visYears[[6]]; length(dat[[1]]); names(dat) ranker <- dat$Total.Value.of.all.Species/dat$Effort df1 <- data.frame(TR = dat$Total.Value.of.all.Species, Plaice.Catch = dat$Plaice.Catch, Sole.Catch = dat$Sole.Catch, Effort = dat$Effort, ranker) ordDf1 <- df1[order(ranker, decreasing = TRUE), ] ordDf1[1:20,] ###Plot Data Effort <- cumsum(ordDf1$Effort) Catch.Plaice <- cumsum(ordDf1$Plaice.Catch) Catch.Sole <- cumsum(ordDf1$Sole.Catch) library(lattice) xyplot(Catch.Plaice ~ Effort, type = "l", col = "green") xyplot(Catch.Sole ~ Effort, type = "l", col = "red")
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.