Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byPatience Miller Modified over 8 years ago
1
Chapter 4: Measuring Welfare
2
Introduction: This chapter has been much focused on the problems of measurement. The aim of this chapter is to clarify some of the problems involved in constructing a method of measuring whether people are better off and, if so, to what extent. The student should be familiar with some concepts and skills in measuring the welfare economics. He should know: -Old and new welfare economics. - Cardinal and Ordinal Preference. - Price Indices (Laspeyres & Paasche) -Retail Price Index -Slutsky equivalent -Human Development Indices. -Gender Development Indices.
3
2. Utility in the development of welfare economics: Old and new welfare economics. - Welfare Economics: studies people’s well-being in different economic situations. -There are two interpretations of utility: Old and New welfare economics: -The 'old welfare economics' assumed that the concept of utility had a wide range of application, covering both mental and physical aspects of well-being. -Two assumptions characterize the old welfare economics: 1) Utility can be thought of in cardinal terms. it is measurable and can be added up. 2) Interpersonal comparisons of utility are unproblematic. it would be reasonable to make judgments such as 'A obtained more utility from driving the Ferrari than B did'.
4
New welfare economics: -Rejects the old welfare assumptions. Utility is not observable and it is not measurable. -The 'new welfare economics' relied on a narrower, more subjective interpretation of utility as a state of mind, thereby driving a block between the mental and physical aspects of well-being. -looked to the principle of Pareto efficiency and the concept of the perfectly competitive market as the basis for a new welfare economics. -The new welfare economics relies on indifference curve analysis which assumes only ordinal utility.
5
2.3 A re-examination of the concept of utility: As a result of debating, between the new welfare economists and Wittgensteinian philosophers, the subjective awareness or 'inner' knowledge has become only one of the criteria we use in learning and applying such 'mental' terms as happiness. It is possible to drive a 'logical wedge' between feelings which can be felt but not observed, and behaviour which can be observed but not felt. The concept of depression 'spans' both what is felt and what is observed. The concept of utility, on this interpretation, spans both the subjective feeling of happiness or satisfaction and the public behaviour of consumption. According to this line of thought, two conclusions about welfare economics seem to follow: 1. First, the standard practice among economists of using income or expenditure as proxies for utility is found more a reasonable procedure which recognizes the way in which experience and behaviour are inextricably intertwined. 2. Second, a welfare economics, capable of making interpersonal comparisons of utility, would be likely to take a more positive attitude towards the redistribution of income and government intervention in markets than the new welfare economics, with its reliance on Pareto efficiency achieved through perfectly competitive markets.
6
3.The measurement of household well-being: Definition: The standard of living is the value of the goods and services available for consumption by each member of the population. In neoclassical microeconomics, the standard of living is measured by the utility, or preference satisfaction, consisting in consumption. For explanation purposes we assume that standard of living is expressed as the ability to consume a specific bundle of goods. Therefore, there are two methods in measuring changes in the cost of reaching a specific standard of living: -Laspeyres index. -Paasche Index. Laspeyres Index (L)= cost of bundle A at year 2 prices cost of bundle A at year 1 prices Laspeyres Index is base weighted, explain. L = PG2 G1 + PF2 F1 PG1 G1 + PF1 F1 Solve exercise 4.1 page 127
7
Figure 4.1 Slutsky compensation variation Z A A*A* SLT B * * M Z F2 F1 G1G2Good G Good f Consider the choices a household makes between two goods F and G in two particular years. Figure 4.1 shows that in year 1 with budget constraint ZS, the household consumes bundle A, which contains F1 of good F and G1 of good G. In year 2 the price of good G falls while that of good F is unchanged, and the budget constraint therefore pivots from ZS to ZT. In response to this price change, the household chooses a new bundle, B, in which F2 of good F and G2 of good are consumed. Now let us apply this piece of analysis to the measurement of changes in the cost of reaching the reference level standard of living, represented by the bundle of goods, A, consumed in year 1.
8
After the fall in the price of G, the household moves to a new equilibrium position at point B. Being able to buy more of both F and G, the household is clearly better off. The question is, how much better off? In order to answer that question, we need a way of comparing the value of the bundle of goods purchased in year 1 with that purchased in year 2, represented by points A and B respectively on Figure 4.1. It is the income effect that measures how much better off the household is as a result of the price change. Substitution and income effects are, respectively, movements along and movements between indifference curves, but because we do not know where the indifference curves are, we need to work with a Slutsky approximation to the income effect. We can see this by drawing a new budget constraint ML parallel to ZT but passing through point A. Suppose the intermediate point A * divides the change in consumption into a substitution effect and an income effect, so that the Slutsky approximation to the substitution effect is now shown by the movement from A to A*, and the Slutsky approximation to the income effect by the movement from A * to B. The amount by which the household is better off as a result of the fall in the price of G is equal to the cut in money income that would be needed to restrict the household to buying the same bundle after the price fall. This compensating variation is represented in Figure 4.1 by the gap between the two budget lines ZT and ML.
9
The budget constraint ML represents the cost to the individual of consuming bundle A at the new set of prices. To measure by how much this cost has changed, ML can be compared with the original budget constraint ZS, which represents the cost of consuming bundle A at the old set of prices. By using the formula for the budget constraint, we take the ratio of the two terms, then we get the Laspeyres price index as following: Laspeyres Index (L)= cost of bundle A at year 2 prices cost of bundle A at year 1 prices -Laspeyres Index is base weighted, explain? -L = P G2 G 1 + P F2 F 1 P G1 G1 + P F1 F1 When, Laspeyres index is more than 1, this means that the cost of living has risen and that means the cost of maintaining the same standard of living and the household is therefore worse off to this extent and the contrary is correct.
10
Figure 4.2 Slutsky equivalent variation A B*B* SS-S- T B * * Z-Z- Z F2 F1 G1G2Good G Good f The alternative idea is to choose the bundle of goods the household consumes after the fall in the price of good G as the reference level of the standard of living. This approach makes use of the equivalent variation and is known as the current-weighted or the Paasche price index. Figure 4.2 shows the same movement of the budget constraint from ZS to ZT, in response to the price change. Once again, the household's consumption moves from bundle A to bundle B. Assuming that the household starts off at bundle A, how much extra income would it need to obtain bundle B, without a price change? This hypothetical change in income is known as the Slutskv equivalent variation because it can be seen as being equivalent to the price change. To specify the equivalent variation on Figure 4.2, a line Z'S' parallel to ZS is drawn through the new bundle. The movement from A to B can now be explained in two steps. First, the consumer receives an equivalent variation of income from A to B*, say, and, second, there is a substitution effect from B* to B. The reduction in the price of G generates an increase in income (the equivalent variation) which is followed by a substitution out of F and into G. 3.2 The equivalent variation and the Paasche index *
11
This time the idea is to divide the income needed to buy bundle B in year 2 (that is, the quantities of F and G consumed in year 2 multiplied by their prices in year 2) by the income that would have been needed to consume bundle B at year 1 prices. If we take the ratio of these two terms we get the Paasche price index Paasche Index (P)= cost of bundle B at year 2 prices cost of bundle B at year 1 prices P = P G2 G2 + P F2 F2 P G1 G2 + P F1 F2 Paasche Index is current weighted, explain.. Solve exercise 4.2 page 129
12
Figure 4.3 A change in relative price A SK B * P Z GGood G Good F This potential disparity between different ways of calculating the cost of living is known as the price index problem. Its occurrence can be explained by looking at a shift in the budget constraint when both the prices change. Assume that the price of G falls and the price of F increases. The budget constraint ZS in Figure 4.3 shifts to PK, In response to the price changes the consumer moves from bundle A to a new bundle B. 3.3 Comparing Laspeyres and Paasche price indices: * Question: Draw in the compensating and equivalent variations on Figure 4.3. Does the cost of living increase? Answer: To specify the compensating variation, a new line P'K' must be drawn parallel to the new budget constraint PK. This shows how much income is required to compensate the household for the change in relative price.
13
Figure 4.4 A change in relative price A SKS-S- P Z-Z- Good G Good F 3.3 Comparing Laspeyres and Paasche price indices: * Figure 4.4(b) by drawing a new line Z'S' parallel to ZS. The movement from ZS to Z'S' shows how much income is required to take the household from A to B without a price change. So by this equivalent variation the consumer is better off at B than at A and the price change is equivalent to an increase in income. This would be reflected in a Paasche cost-of living index less than 100 since the household have become better off. Z Figure 4.4 A change in relative price A SK B * P Z Good G Good F * Figure 4.4(a) shows that the household is worse off after the price changes, according to the compensating variation. To get back from B to A there has to be an increase in income. If the household needs to be compensated with more income to gel back to the original bundle A. it must be worse off. This increase in the cost of living would be reflected in a Laspeyres index higher than 100, showing that the household has indeed become worse off. K*K* P*P* * B
14
5.2 Capabilities and functionings: The United Nations (DP) has been using the “capabilities approach” as a framework for the measurement of the well being and agency of people all over the world. The applications of this approach are: 1. The Human Development Index (HDI) is a systematic attempt to measure what the people of a particular country are able to do and to be, it offers an account of agency as well as being. - The HDI is constructed from data on a number of key indicators of human functioning, including life expectancy at birth, health status, educational opportunities employment and political rights. -All these indicators are aggregated for each countries and expressed as an index number, which enables countries to be ranked in terms of human development. 2. The Gender related Development Index (GDI) – is a composite indicator that measures the average achievement of a population in the same dimensions as the HDI while adjusting for gender inequalities in distribution of resources and opportunities between the genders. It uses the same variables as the HDI, but disaggregated by gender.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.