Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Chapter 36 Public Goods.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Chapter 36 Public Goods."— Presentation transcript:

1 Chapter 36 Public Goods

2 Public Goods -- Definition
A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. Nonexcludable -- all consumers can consume the good. Nonrival -- one consumer’s consumption doesn’t diminish another’s.

3 Public Goods -- Examples
Broadcast radio and TV programs. National defense. Public highways (nearly). Clean air. National parks. A good climate.

4 We will need to recall from chapter 14 that:
A consumer’s reservation price for a unit of a good is the maximum he/she is willing to pay for it. If: Consumer’s wealth is w Utility when not having the good is U(w, 0) Utility of paying p and having one unit of the good is U(w-p, 1) Then the reservation price r is defined by

5 When Should a Public Good Be Provided?
One unit of the good costs c. Two consumers, A and B. Individual payments for providing the public good are gA and gB. the good will be provided only if gA + gB  c

6 Call the utility functions UA and UB and assume that A’s income is wA and B’s is wB.
Payments are individually rational if and which implies that gA ≤rA and gB ≤ rB

7 And if and then it is Pareto-improving to supply the unit of good
(It is Pareto-improving only if one inequality holds with < and the other at least with ≤) If c ≤ rA + rB it must be pareto-efficient to supply the good.

8 Free-riding Suppose c < rA and 0 < rB .
Then A would supply the good even if B made no contribution. Then B would enjoy the good for free; be free-riding.

9 Private Provision of a Public Good?
Suppose c < rA and c < rB . Neither A nor B will supply the good alone. Yet, if c < rA + rB both could be better off if the good is supplied with a payment scheme where c < gA + gB ; gA < rA and gB < rB But A and B may try to free-ride on each other, causing no good to be supplied.

10 Free-Riding - an example
Suppose A and B each have just two actions -- individually supply a public good, or not. Cost of supply c = 100. Payoff to A from the good = 80. Payoff to B from the good = 65. > 100, so it is possible to supply the good and make both better off.

11 Player B Don’t Buy Buy Buy Player A Don’t Buy (Don’t’ Buy, Don’t Buy) is the unique NE

12 But (Don’t buy, Don’t buy) is not efficient.
Why? If each pays part of the cost: For example, A contributes 60 and B contributes 40. Payoff to A from the good = 40 > 0. Payoff to B from the good = 25 > 0. Any division of 100 such that gA≤80 and gB ≤ 65 will do.

13 Player B Don’t Contribute Contribute Contribute Player A
With cost-sharing there are two NE. But even if the good is supplied, there can still be some free-riding. Player B Don’t Contribute Contribute Contribute Player A Don’t Contribute

14 Variable Public Good Quantities
E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park. c(G) is the production cost of G units of public good. Two individuals, A and B. Private consumptions are xA, xB.

15 Budget allocations must satisfy
MRSA & MRSB are A & B’s marg. rates of substitution between the private and public goods. Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is

16 MRSA is A’s utility-preserving compensation in private good units for a one-unit reduction in public good. Similarly for B. is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit. the total amount of private good that A and B together are willing to give up to have G increased by 1 unit

17 If , making 1unit less of the public good releases more private good than the compensation payment requires  Pareto-improvement from reduced G. If the payment A and B are willing to make for 1 unit of public good provides more than 1 unit  Pareto-improvement from increased G.

18 Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires
Suppose there are n consumers; i = 1,…,n. Then efficient public good production requires

19 Free-Riding Revisited
When is free-riding individually rational? Individuals can contribute only positively to public good supply; nobody can lower the supply level. Individual utility-maximization may require a lower public good level. Free-riding is rational in such cases.

20 subject to xB + gB = wB and gB≥0
Each agent decides how much to contribute based on how much everybody else is expected to contribute. For example: Given A that contributes gA units of public good, B’s problem is to choose xB and gB so as to maximise UB(xB, gA+ gB) subject to xB + gB = wB and gB≥0

21 B’s budget constraint; slope = -1
B’s endowment if A pays gA for the public good gA xB wB

22 G B’s budget constraint; slope = -1 gB = 0 (free-riding) is best for B gA gB<0 is not possible xB

23 Demand Revelation A scheme that makes it rational for individuals to reveal truthfully their private valuations of a public good is a revelation mechanism. For example, the Groves-Clarke taxation scheme

24 Assume: N individuals; i = 1,…,N. All have quasi-linear preferences.
vi is individual i’s true (private) valuation of the public good. Individual i must provide ci private good units if the public good is supplied. ni = vi - ci is net value, for i = 1,…,N. Can be Pareto-improving to supply the public good if

25 ni = vi - ci is net value, for i = 1,…,N.
If and or and then individual j is pivotal; i.e. changes the supply decision.

26 What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on the others?
If then is the loss. If then is the loss.

27 The GC tax scheme: Assign a cost ci to each individual. Each agent states a public good net valuation, si. Public good is supplied if otherwise not.

28 A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from supply to not supply pays a tax of
A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from not supply to supply pays a tax of

29 GC tax scheme implements efficient supply of the public good.
Note: Taxes are not paid to other individuals, but to some other agent outside the market.

30 An example: 3 persons; A, B and C.
Valuations of the public good are: 40 for A, 50 for B, 110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is 180. 180 < so it is efficient to supply the good. Assign c1 = 60, c2 = 60, c3 = 60.

31 B & C’s net valuations sum to (50 - 60) + (110 - 60) = 40 > 0.
A, B & C’s net valuations sum to ( ) + 40 = 20 > 0. So A is not pivotal. A’s true net value is 40 – 60 = -20 If sA > -20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of 20 to him, more likely.

32 If B and C are truthful, then what net valuation sA should A state?
If sA > -20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of 20 to him, more likely. If sA < -20 but not enough to make A pivotal his loss is still 20. A prevents supply by becoming pivotal, only if sA + ( ) + ( ) < 0; To be pivotal A must state sA < -40.

33 Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of -10 + 50 = 40,
A’s net payoff is = -60 < -20. A can do no better than state the truth; sA = -20.

34 Use the same method to show that
Exercise: Use the same method to show that B is not pivotal B can do no better than state the truth; sB = -10. C is pivotal C can do no better than state the truth; sC = 50.


Download ppt "Chapter 36 Public Goods."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google