Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

General Equilibrium and Economic Efficiency

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "General Equilibrium and Economic Efficiency"— Presentation transcript:

1 General Equilibrium and Economic Efficiency
Chapter 16 General Equilibrium and Economic Efficiency

2 Topics to be Discussed General Equilibrium Analysis
Efficiency in Exchange Equity and Efficiency Efficiency in Production Chapter 16 2 2

3 Topics to be Discussed The Gains from Free Trade
On Overview--The Efficiency of Competitive Markets Why Markets Fail Chapter 16 2 3

4 General Equilibrium Analysis
Up to this point, we have been focused on partial equilibrium analysis Activity in one market is has little or no effect on other markets. Market interrelationships can be important Complements and substitutes Increase in firms input demand can cause market price of the input and product to rise Chapter 16 4

5 General Equilibrium Analysis
To study how markets interrelate, we can use general equilibrium analysis Simultaneous determination of the prices and quantities in all relevant markets, taking into account feedback effects. The feedback effect is the price or quantity adjustment in one market caused by price and quantity adjustments in related markets Chapter 16 5

6 Two Interdependent Markets – Moving to General Equilibrium
Scenario The competitive markets of: DVD rentals Movie theater tickets These goods are substitutes Changing prices in one market are likely to affect the other market Chapter 16 6

7 Two Interdependent Markets – Moving to General Equilibrium
Scenario Equilibrium price of movies is $6.00 Equilibrium price of DVD rentals are $3.00 Government places a $1.00 tax on each movie ticket Need to look at effect of tax on Market for DVDs Feedback effects in Movie market Chapter 16

8 Two Interdependent Markets – Movies and DVDs
$1 tax on each movie ticket causes supply to fall General Equilibrium Analysis: Increase in movie ticket prices increases demand for videos. Price Price S*M SV SM D’V DM Q’V $3.50 $6.35 Q’M DV QV $3.00 $6.00 QM Number of Movie Tickets Number of Videos

9 Two Interdependent Markets – Movies and DVDs
The increase in the price of videos increases the demand for movies. General Equilibrium Analysis: The Feedback effects continue. Price Price $3.58 Q*V D*V DM SM $6.00 QM $6.35 Q’M S*M D*M $6.82 Q*M DV SV QV $3.00 Q’V $3.50 Q”M $6.75 D’M D’V Number of Movie Tickets Number of Videos Chapter 16

10 Two Interdependent Markets – Movies and DVDs
Observation Without considering the feedback effect with general equilibrium, the impact of the tax would have been underestimated This is an important consideration for policy makers. You can check for yourself that in the market for complements, the tax would be overestimated Chapter 16 20

11 Reaching General Equilibrium
Must be able to determine the equilibrium price of both movies and DVDs simultaneously We must simultaneously find two prices that equate quantity demanded and quantity supplied in all related markets The requires finding the solution to four equations: demand and supply for DVDs and Movies Chapter 16

12 The Interdependence of International Markets
Brazil and the United States compete in the world soybean market so one market can affect the other. Brazil limited exports of soybeans in the late 1960’s and early 1970’s causing price in Brazil to fall. Eventually the export controls were to be removed, and Brazilian exports were expected to increase. Chapter 16 22

13 The Interdependence of International Markets
Expectation was based on partial equilibrium analysis Program actually increased the price and production of soybeans in US as well as US exports This caused brazil to have difficulties exporting even after control was removed Can show how each market was effected and compare to general equilibrium analysis Chapter 16

14 Soybean Exports – Brazil and US

15 Efficiency in Exchange
We showed before that competitive markets are efficient because consumer and producer surplus are maximized We can study this in more detail by examining an exchange economy Market in which two or more consumers trade two goods among themselves Same for two countries Chapter 16

16 Efficiency in Exchange
An efficient allocation of goods is one where no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off Pareto efficiency Voluntary trade between two parties is mutually beneficial and increases economic efficiency. Chapter 16 25

17 The Advantages of Trade
Assumptions Two consumers (countries) Two goods Both people know each others preferences Exchanging goods involves zero transaction costs James & Karen have a total of 10 units of food and 6 units of clothing. Chapter 16 26

18 The Advantage of Trade Individual Initial Allocation Trade Final Allocation James 7F, 1C -1F, +1C 6F, 2C Karen 3F, 5C +1F, -1C 4F, 4C To determine if they are better off, we need to know the preferences for food and clothing Chapter 16 28

19 The Advantage of Trade Karen has a lot of clothing and little food.
MRS of food for clothing is 3 To get 1 unit of food, she will give up 3 units of clothing James’ MRS of food for clothing is only ½ He will give up ½ unit if clothing for 1 unit of food Chapter 16

20 The Advantage of Trade There is room for trade
James values clothing more than Karen Karen values food more than James Karen willing to give up 3 units of clothing to get 1 unit of food, but James is willing to take only ½ unit of clothing for 1 unit of food Actual terms of trade are determined through bargaining Trade for 1 unit of food will fall between ½ and 3 units of clothing Chapter 16

21 The Advantage of Trade Suppose Karen offers James 1 unit of clothing for 1 unit of food James will have more clothing, which he values food Karen will have more food, which she values more Whenever two consumers’ MRSs are different, there is room for mutually beneficial trade Allocation of resources is inefficient Chapter 16

22 The Advantage of Trade From this analysis we obtain an important result: An allocation of goods is efficient only if the goods are distributed so that the marginal rate of substitution between any pair of goods is the same for all consumers. Chapter 16

23 The Edgeworth Box Diagram
A diagram showing all possible allocations of either two goods between two people or of two inputs between two production processes is called an Edgeworth Box Chapter 16 29

24 The Edgeworth Box Diagram
Food is measured across the horizontal axis Clothing is measured on the vertical axis Length of box is the total amount of food – 10 units Height of box is the total amount of clothing – 6 units Chapter 16

25 The Edgeworth Box Diagram
Each point describes the market baskets of both consumers James’ basket is read from origin OJ Karen’s basket is read from origin OK, in the reverse direction James has 7 units of food and 1 unit of clothing – point A Karen has 3 units of food and 5 units of clothing – point A from different axis Chapter 16

26 Exchange in an Edgeworth Box
Karen’s Food 10F 3F 7F 0K 6C The initial allocation before trade is A: James has 7F and 1C & Karen has 3F and 5C. James’s Clothing Karen’s Clothing 1C 5C A 6C 0J 10F James’s Food

27 Exchange in an Edgeworth Box
10F 0K 0J 6C James’s Clothing Karen’s James’s Food Karen’s Food 1C 5C 3F 7F A 4F 6F The allocation after trade is B: James has 6F and 2C & Karen has 4F and 4C. B 2C 4C +1C -1F Chapter 16

28 Efficient Allocations
A trade from A to B makes both Karen and James better off Is it efficient? If James’s and Karen’s MRS are the same at B the allocation is efficient. This depends on the shape of their indifference curves. Chapter 16 35

29 Efficient Allocations
James’ indifference curves are drawn as we usually see them Karen’s indifference curves are rotated 180o convex to her axis The indifference curves that go through point A have different slopes and therefore different MRSs The allocation is not efficient Chapter 16

30 Efficient Allocations
The shaded area between these two indifference curves represents all the possible allocations of food and clothing that would make both James and Karen better off than A Describes all mutually beneficial trades Chapter 16

31 Efficient Allocations
We can see both parties are better off at point B since they both end up on a higher indifference curve Not efficient since MRSs different – indifference curve have different slopes Although a trade might make both parties better off, the new allocation is not necessarily efficient Chapter 16

32 Efficient Allocations
How do these parties reach an efficient allocation? When there is no more room for trade When their MRSs are equal They will keep trading, reaching higher indifference curves, until they can no longer do so and still make each better off This is when indifference curves are tangent – they have the same slope and same MRS Chapter 16

33 Efficiency in Exchange
Karen’s Food 10F 0K 6C A: UJ1 = UK1, but the MRS is not equal. All combinations in the shaded area are preferred to A. UJ1 UK1 James’s Clothing Karen’s Clothing Gains from trade A 0J 6C James’s Food 10F Chapter 16 39

34 Efficiency in Exchange
Karen’s Food 10F 0K 6C D is also a possible efficient allocation depending on bargaining At point C, MRSs are equal and allocation is efficient Point B is on higher IC but is not efficient UJ3 UK1 UJ1 A UJ2 James’s Clothing Karen’s Clothing UK2 D UK3 C B 0J 6C James’s Food 10F Chapter 16

35 Efficiency in Exchange
Any move outside the shaded area will make one person worse off (closer to their origin). B is a mutually beneficial trade--higher indifference curve for each person. Trade may be beneficial but not efficient. MRS is equal when indifference curves are tangent and the allocation is efficient. A Karen’s Clothing Karen’s Food UK1 UK2 UK3 James’s James’s Food UJ1 UJ2 UJ3 B C D 10F 0K 0J 6C Chapter 16 39

36 Efficiency in Exchange
The Contract Curve To find all possible efficient allocations of food and clothing between Karen and James, we would look for all points of tangency between each of their indifference curves. The contract curve shows all the efficient allocations of goods between two consumers, or of two inputs between two production functions Chapter 16 43

37 The Contract Curve 0K G F E 0J Karen’s Food E, F, & G are
Pareto efficient . G Contract Curve F E James’s Clothing Karen’s Clothing 0J James’s Food Chapter 16 47

38 Contract curve All points of tangency between the indifference curves are efficient. MRS of individuals is the same No more room for trade The contract curve shows all allocations that are Pareto efficient. Pareto efficient allocation occurs when further trade will make someone worse off. Chapter 16 48

39 Efficiency in Exchange
Application: The policy implication of Pareto efficiency when removing import quotas: Remove quotas US Consumers gain Some US workers lose Removal of quotas and subsidies to the workers Chapter 16 50

40 Efficiency in Exchange
US consumers would be better off and after a time, the US workers are no worse off and might be better off Package will increase efficiency Efficiency therefore can be reached with the combined set of changes leaves someone better off and no one worse off Chapter 16

41 Efficiency in Exchange
Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market Competitive markets have many actual or potential buyers and sellers, so if people do not like the terms of an exchange, they can look for another seller who offers better terms. Chapter 16 51

42 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
There are many Jameses and Karens. They are price takers Relative price of food and clothing = 1 Trade depends on relative prices, not actual prices Chapter 16 52

43 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
We can show opportunities for trade for many consumers When prices of food and clothing are equal, we can show the price line, PP’ with a slope of –1 Shows all possible allocations that exchange can achieve James buys 2 clothing for 2 food: A to C Karen buys 2 food for 2 clothing: A to C Both increase satisfaction Chapter 16

44 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
10F Karen’s Food 0K 6C Price Line Begin at A: Each James buys 2C and sells 2F moving from Uj1 to Uj2, which is preferred (A to C). Begin at A: Each Karen buys 2F and sells 2C moving from UK1 to UK2, which is preferred (A to C). P P’ UJ2 UJ1 UK1 UK2 Karen’s Clothing C James’s Clothing A 6C 0J 10F James’s Food Chapter 16

45 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
The amount of clothing that Karen wanted to sell is equal to the amount of clothing that James wanted to buy An equilibrium is a set of prices at which the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied in every market Also called competitive equilibrium Chapter 16

46 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
Not all prices lead to equilibrium If the MRSs of the players is not equal, then we are not in equilibrium If the price of food is 1 and price of clothing is 3 James is unwilling to trade, MRS = ½ Karen is happy to sell clothing at that price but has no one to sell to Market is in disequilibrium Chapter 16

47 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
Disequilibrium is only temporary in competitive market Excess demand will cause price to rise Excess supply will cause price to fall In our example, we have excess supply of clothing and excess demand of food Should expect the price of food to increase relative to price of clothing Prices adjust until equilibrium is reached Chapter 16

48 Economic Efficiency of Competitive Markets
As shown before, we can see that the allocation in a competitive equilibrium is economically efficient The efficient point must occur where the two indifference curves are tangent If not, one of the consumers can increase their utility and be better off Chapter 16 63

49 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
In a general equilibrium setting where all markets are perfectly competitive, we can show the same result Best example of Adam Smith’s invisible hand Economy will automatically allocate all resources efficiently without need for regulatory control Supports argument for less government intervention and more highly competitive markets Chapter 16 65

50 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
First Theorem of Welfare Economics If everyone trades in a competitive market place, all mutually beneficial trades will be completed and the resulting equilibrium allocation of resources will be economically efficient Welfare economics involves the normative evaluation of markets and economic policy Chapter 16 66

51 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
Competitive equilibrium Because the indifference curves are tangent, all MRSs are equal between consumers Because each indifference curve is tangent to the price line, each person’s MRS is equal to the price ratio of the two goods Chapter 16 67

52 Consumer Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
Difficult for efficient allocation with many consumer and producers unless all markets are perfectly competitive Efficient outcomes can also be achieved by centralized system Competitive outcome preferred since consumers and producers can better assess their preferences and supply Chapter 16

53 Equity and Efficiency Although there are many efficient allocations, some may be more fair than others The difficult question is what is the most equitable allocation? We can show that there is no reason to believe that efficient allocation from competitive markets will give an equitable allocation Chapter 16

54 The Utility Possibilities Frontier
From the Edgeworth box we showed a two person exchange The utility possibilities frontier represents all allocations that are efficient in terms of the utility levels of the two individuals Shows the levels of satisfaction that are achieved when the two individuals have reached the contract curve Chapter 16

55 The Utility Possibilities Frontier
OJ – James has zero utility OK – Karen has zero utility E, F, G – points on contract curve H – inefficient – can do better in shaded area L - unobtainable Karen’s Utility OJ L E F G H OK James’ Utility Chapter 16

56 The Utility Possibilities Frontier
Are all efficient points equitable? Efficient points E or F make both persons better off without making one worse off from H If only possible points are H and G, can argue that one is more equitable to James and one to Karen Karen’s Utility OJ E F G H OK James’ Utility Chapter 16

57 The Utility Possibilities Frontier
From previous example, can see that an inefficient allocation might be more equitable than an efficient one. But how do we define an equitable allocation? It depends on what we believe equity to entail Requires interpersonal comparisons of utility Chapter 16

58 Social Welfare Functions
Weights are often applied to individual’s utility to determine what is socially desirable. How these weights are applied comes from the social welfare functions The utilitarian function weights everyone’s utility to maximize utility for the whole society Chapter 16

59 Social Welfare Functions
Each social welfare function is associated with a particular view of equity Some views of equity do not assign weights and cannot be represented by a welfare function Competitive market process is equitable because it rewards those who are most able and work hardest Believes competitive equilibrium would be most equitable Chapter 16

60 Social Welfare Functions
The Rawlsian view individuals don’t know what their endowment will be Rawls argues that if you don’t know your own fate, you will opt for the system in which the least well-off person is treated reasonably well. The most equitable allocation maximizes the utility of the least well-off person in society Chapter 16

61 Social Welfare Functions
An egalitarian view believes that goods should be equally shared by all individuals in society Could have situation where reward more productive people thereby producing more goods and then having more to reallocate to all of society Chapter 16

62 Four Views of Equity Egalitarian
All members of society receive equal amount of goods Rawlsian Maximize the utility of the least-well-off person Utilitarian Maximize the total utility of all members of society Market - Oriented The market outcome is the most equitable Chapter 16

63 Equity and Perfect Competition
A competitive equilibrium can occur at any point on the contract curve depending on the initial allocation. Since not all competitive equilibriums are equitable, we rely on the government to help reach equity by redistributing income. Taxes Pubic services Chapter 16

64 Equity and Perfect Competition
Must a society that wants to be more equitable necessarily operate in an inefficient world? Second Theorem of Welfare Economics If individual preferences are convex, then every efficient allocation (every point on the contract curve) is a competitive equilibrium for some initial allocation of goods. Chapter 16

65 Equity and Perfect Competition
Any equilibrium that is equitable can be achieved by redistributing resources and may be efficient Typical ways to redistribute goods, however, are costly Taxes lead to bad incentives Firms devote fewer resources to avoid taxes Encourage individuals to work less Chapter 16

66 Efficiency in Production
From the discussion of exchange of two goods, we can extend to the efficient use of inputs used for production. Assume: Two fixed inputs: capital and labor Produce same two goods: good and clothing Many consumers own inputs to production and earn income from selling them Income allocated between goods Chapter 16

67 Efficiency in Production
Using the Edgeworth box diagram, we can show efficient use of inputs in production Labor on horizontal axis Capital on vertical axis 50 hours of labor and 30 hours of capital available Each origin is an output Chapter 16

68 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Labor in Clothing Production 50L 15L 35L 0C 30K The initial allocation is A. Every combination of labor and capital used to produce two goods is represented as point in box Capital in Clothing Production Capital in Food Production 5K 25K A 30K 0F 50L Labor in Food Production

69 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Each point in box represents the labor and capital inputs in the production of food and clothing. Can use production isoquants to show levels of output produced with each combination of inputs 3 isoquants representing 50, 60 and 80 units of food 3 isoquants representing 10, 25 and30 units of clothing Chapter 16

70 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Labor in Clothing Production 50L 15L 0C 30K 3 isoquants representing food production 80F 3 isoquants representing clothing production Capital in Clothing Production 10C Capital in Food Production 60F 25C 50F 30C A 5K 25K 30K 0F 35L 50L Labor in Food Production

71 Production in an Edgeworth Box
To find efficient production, must find different combinations of inputs used to produce the two outputs An allocation of inputs is technically efficient if the output of one good cannot be increased without decreasing the output of another goods Chapter 16

72 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Production at point A is inefficient since we can increase production of both goods. Shaded area indicates increases in production of both goods if begin at A Allocation A could exist if a labor union market has enforced inefficient work rules Chapter 16

73 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Labor in Clothing Production 50L 15L 0C 30K Any place in shaded area will increase efficiency from allocation A. Can move from A to B or C which increases efficiency. 80F Capital in Clothing Production 10C D Capital in Food Production 60F 25C 50F 30C C B A 5K 25K 30K 0F 35L 50L Labor in Food Production

74 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Points B and C are efficient allocations and therefore lie on the production contract curve Curve showing all technically efficient combinations of inputs. Curve connects the origins, OF and OC All points on curve are tangencies between two isoquants Chapter 16

75 Production in an Edgeworth Box
Labor in Clothing Production 50L 15L 0C 30K 80F Capital in Clothing Production 10C Production Contract Curve D Capital in Food Production 60F 25C 50F 30C C B A 5K 25K 30K 0F 35L 50L Labor in Food Production

76 Producer Equilibrium – Competitive Input Markets
If input markets are competitive, an efficient point will be achieved In competitive input markets Wage rate, w, will be equal in all industries Rental rate of capital, r, will be equal in all industries Chapter 16

77 Producer Equilibrium – Competitive Input Markets
We saw before that if producers minimize costs, they will choose inputs to the point where the ratio of the marginal products of the two inputs is equal to the ratio of input prices: Chapter 16

78 Producer Equilibrium – Competitive Input Markets
Ratio of marginal products is the same as the marginal rate of technical substitution of labor for capital: Chapter 16

79 Producer Equilibrium – Competitive Input Markets
The MRTS is the slope of the isoquant, so competitive equilibrium exists only if: Slopes of the isoquants are equal to one another These also equal the ratio of the prices of two inputs Competitive equilibrium lies on the production contract curve, and the competitive equilibrium is efficient in production Chapter 16

80 Production Possibilities Frontier
PPF shows the various combinations of two goods that can be produced with fixed quantities of inputs. Frontier is derived from the production contract curve Points on PPF show efficiently produced levels of both goods Chapter 16

81 Production Possibilities Frontier
Point A is inefficient Points B, C and D are efficient All points in triangle ABC completely utilize capital and labor but distortion in labor market leads to inefficient use Clothing(units) OF B C A D OC Food (units) Chapter 16

82 Production Possibilities Frontier
PPF is downward sloping In order to produce more of one good, must give up producing some of the other good PPF is concave Slope is the MRTS which increases as the level of production of food increases Chapter 16

83 Production Possibilities Frontier
Marginal rate of transformation (MRT) of food for clothing is the magnitude of the slope of the frontier at each point Amount of one good that must be given up to produce one additional unit of a second good How much clothing must be given up to produce one additional unit of food As we increase the production of food my moving along the PPF, the MRT increases Chapter 16

84 Marginal Rate of Transformation
The productivity of labor and capital differs depending on whether the inputs are used to produce more food or clothing. Starting where only clothing is produced, MP of labor and capital are relatively low Transferring some to food production where MP are relatively high As we do this, MP in food decreases and MP in clothing increases Chapter 16

85 Production Possibilities Frontier
Clothing(units) OF MRT < 1 B  MRT = 1 MRT > 1 D  MRT = 2 OC Food (units) Chapter 16

86 Marginal Rate of Transformation
Can also describe in terms of costs When producing at OF the MC of food is very low and MC of clothing is very high When MRT is low, so is the ratio of the MC of producing food to clothing Slope of PPF measures the MC of producing one good relative to the MC of producing the other Chapter 16

87 Output Efficiency For efficiency, Efficiency means MRS = MRT
Good produced at minimum cost Must be produced in combinations that match peoples willingness to pay MRS = consumer’s WTP for additional food by consuming less clothing MRT = cost of additional unit of food in terms of producing less clothing Efficiency means MRS = MRT Chapter 16

88 Output Efficiency What if MRT  MRS Suppose MRT = 1 and MRS =2
Consumer willing to give up 2 units of clothing to get 1 unit of food Cost of getting additional food is only 1 unit of lost clothing Too little food is being produced Food production must increase, MRS falls and MRT increase until two are equal again Chapter 16

89 Output Efficiency MRS = MRT 60 PPF Indifference Curve 100
Clothing(units) 60 Indifference Curve PPF Food (units) 100 Chapter 16

90 Efficiency in Output Markets
For perfectly competitive markets, all consumers allocate their budgets so their MRS between two good are equal to the ratio of prices Profit maximizing firms produce output to the point where price is equal to MC MRT is equal to the MRS Chapter 16

91 Efficiency in Output Markets
Efficiency in competitive markets achieved when separate production and consumption Market price ratio of P1F/P1C Food and clothing produced at A where price ratio equals MRT This price causes consumer at B maximizing utility Chapter 16

92 Efficiency in Output Markets
Produce at A Consume at B Inefficient Need to move to C Clothing(units) PF1/PC1 PF*/PC* U2 C1 A F1 U1 F2 B C2 C C* F* Food (units) Chapter 16

93 The Gains from Free Trade
We have showed gains from trade in an Edgeworth box, but what about gains from trade with two countries where one has the comparative advantage A country has a comparative advantage over another country in the production of a good if the first country can produce the good at a lower opportunity cost than the other country Chapter 16

94 The Gains from Free Trade
EX: Two countries producing two goods Holland and Italy Cheese and Wine Holland has comparative advantage in cheese production Italy as comparative advantage in wine production Trade is good for both countries Chapter 16

95 The Gains from Free Trade
Hours of Labor Required to Produce Cheese and Wine Cheese (1 LB) Wine (1 GAL) Holland 1 2 Italy 6 3 Chapter 16

96 The Gains from Free Trade
When there is comparative advantage, free trade allows the country to consume outside their PPF Before trade Produces at A on indifference curve U1 where MRT and pre-trade price ratio is 2 Holland would want to export 2 pounds of cheese for 1 gallon of wine Chapter 16

97 The Gains from Free Trade
After trade Suppose they choose to trade 1 gallon of wine for 1 pound of cheese Holland will produce at the point of tangency on the 1/1 price line and PPF – point B Consumption will occur at D, on a higher indifference curve U2 tangent to the trade price line Chapter 16

98 The Gains from Trade Trade allows Holland to consume outside PPF
Cheese (lbs) World Prices Pre-Trade Prices CB B WB U2 Exports U1 A WD D CD Wine (gal) Imports Chapter 16

99 Overview – Efficiency of Competitive Markets
Efficiency in Exchange MRSJFC = MRSKFC MRSJFC = PF/PC = MRSKFC Efficiency in the use of inputs in production MRTSFLK = MRTSCLK MRTSFLK = w/r = MRTSCLK Chapter 16

100 Overview – Efficiency of Competitive Markets
Efficiency in the output market MRTFC = MRSPC (for all consumers) PF = MCF, PC = MCC resulting in MRTFC = MCF/MCC = PF/PC; therefore MRSFC = MRTFC Chapter 16

101 Why Markets Fail Market Power
Those with market power choose the price and quantity Less output is sold than in competitive markets Inefficiency Can have market power as producers or as inputs Chapter 16

102 Why Markets Fail Incomplete Information
Consumers must have accurate information about market prices or production quality for markets to operate efficiency Lack of information can change supply Buy products with no value Don’t buy enough of products with value Some markets may never develop Chapter 16

103 Why Markets Fail Externalities
Market prices do not always reflect the activities of either producers or consumers Consumption or production has indirect effect on other consumption or production not reflected in market prices May be impossible to get insurance because suppliers of insurance lack information Chapter 16

104 Why Markets Fail Public Goods
Nonexclusive, nonrival good that can be made available cheaply but which, once available, is difficult to prevent others from consuming Company thinking about researching a new technology if can’t get patent Once it’s made pubic, others can duplicate it Chapter 16


Download ppt "General Equilibrium and Economic Efficiency"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google