Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS"— Presentation transcript:

1 BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS
Chapter 11 PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS EIGHTH EDITION WALTER NICHOLSON Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

2 Production Function The firm’s production function for a particular good (q) shows the maximum amount of the good that can be produced using alternative combinations of capital (K) and labor (L) q = f(K,L)

3 Marginal Physical Product
To study variation in a single input, we define marginal physical product as the additional output that can be produced by employing one more unit of that input while holding other inputs constant

4 Diminishing Marginal Productivity
The marginal physical product of an input depends on how much of that input is used In general, we assume diminishing marginal productivity

5 Diminishing Marginal Productivity
Because of diminishing marginal productivity, 19th century economist Thomas Malthus worried about the effect of population growth on labor productivity But changes in the marginal productivity of labor over time also depend on changes in other inputs such as capital we need to consider fLK which is often > 0

6 Average Physical Product
Labor productivity is often measured by average productivity Note that APL also depends on the amount of capital employed

7 A Two-Input Production Function
Suppose the production function for flyswatters can be represented by q = f(K,L) = 600K 2L2 - K 3L3 To construct MPL and APL, we must assume a value for K Let K = 10 The production function becomes q = 60,000L L3

8 A Two-Input Production Function
The marginal productivity function is MPL = q/L = 120,000L L2 which diminishes as L increases This implies that q has a maximum value: 120,000L L2 = 0 40L = L2 L = 40 Labor input beyond L=40 reduces output

9 A Two-Input Production Function
To find average productivity, we hold K=10 and solve APL = q/L = 60,000L L2 APL reaches its maximum where APL/L = 60, L = 0 L = 30

10 A Two-Input Production Function
In fact, when L=30, both APL and MPL are equal to 900,000 Thus, when APL is at its maximum, APL and MPL are equal

11 Isoquant Maps To illustrate the possible substitution of one input for another, we use an isoquant map An isoquant shows those combinations of K and L that can produce a given level of output (q0) f(K,L) = q0

12 Isoquant Map Each isoquant represents a different level of output
output rises as we move northeast q = 30 q = 20 K per period L per period

13 Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS)
The slope of an isoquant shows the rate at which L can be substituted for K LA KA KB LB A B K per period - slope = marginal rate of technical substitution (RTS) RTS > 0 and is diminishing for increasing inputs of labor q = 20 L per period

14 Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS)
The marginal rate of technical substitution (RTS) shows the rate at which labor can be substituted for capital while holding output constant along an isoquant

15 RTS and Marginal Productivities
Take the total differential of the production function: Along an isoquant dq = 0, so

16 RTS and Marginal Productivities
Because MPL and MPK will both be nonnegative, RTS will also be nonnegative However, it is not possible to derive a diminishing RTS from the assumption of diminishing marginal productivity alone

17 RTS and Marginal Productivities
To show that isoquants are convex, we would like to show that d(RTS)/dL < 0 Since RTS = fL/fK

18 RTS and Marginal Productivities
Using the fact that dK/dL = -fL/fK along an isoquant and Young’s theorem (fKL = fLK) Because we have assumed fK > 0, the denominator is positive Because fLL and fKK are both assumed to be negative, the ratio will be negative if fKL is positive

19 RTS and Marginal Productivities
Intuitively, it seems reasonable that fKL=fLK should be positive if workers have more capital, they will be more productive But some production functions have fKL < 0 over some input ranges Thus, when we assume diminishing RTS we are assuming that MPL and MPK diminish quickly enough to compensate for any possible negative cross-productivity effects

20 A Diminishing RTS Suppose the production function is
q = f(K,L) = 600K 2L2 - K 3L3 For this production function MPL = fL = 1200K 2L - 3K 3L2 MPK = fK = 1200KL2 - 3K 2L3 These marginal productivities will be positive for values of K and L for which KL < 400

21 A Diminishing RTS Because
fLL = 1200K 2 - 6K 3L fKK = 1200L2 - 6KL3 this production function exhibits diminishing marginal productivities for sufficiently large values of K and L fLL and fKK < 0 if KL > 200

22 A Diminishing RTS Cross differentiation of either of the marginal productivity functions yields fKL = fLK = 2400KL - 9K 2L2 which is positive only for KL < 266

23 A Diminishing RTS Thus, for this production function, RTS is diminishing throughtout the range of K and L where marginal productivities are positive for higher values of K and L, the diminishing marginal productivities are sufficient to overcome the influence of a negative value for fKL to ensure convexity of the isoquants

24 Returns to Scale How does output respond to increases in all inputs together? Suppose that all inputs are doubled, would output double? Returns to scale have been of interest to economists since the days of Adam Smith

25 Returns to Scale Smith identified two forces that come into operation as inputs are doubled greater division of labor and specialization of function loss in efficiency because management may become more difficult given the larger scale of the firm

26 Returns to Scale If the production function is given by q = f(K,L) and all inputs are multiplied by the same positive constant (m > 1), then

27 Returns to Scale It is possible for a production function to exhibit constant returns to scale for some levels of input usage and increasing or decreasing returns for other levels economists refer to the degree of returns to scale with the implicit notion that only a fairly narrow range of variation in input usage and the related level of output is being considered

28 Constant Returns to Scale
Constant returns-to-scale production functions have the useful theoretical property that that the RTS between K and L depends only on the ratio of K to L, not the scale of operation Geometrically, all of the isoquants are “radial blowups” of the unit isoquant

29 Constant Returns to Scale
Along a ray from the origin (constant K/L), the RTS will be the same on all isoquants K per period q = 3 q = 2 q = 1 The isoquants are equally spaced as output expands L per period

30 f(mX1,mX2,…,mXn) = mkf(X1,X2,…,Xn)=mkq
Returns to Scale Returns to scale can be generalized to a production function with n inputs q = f(X1,X2,…,Xn) If all inputs are multiplied by a positive constant m, we have f(mX1,mX2,…,mXn) = mkf(X1,X2,…,Xn)=mkq If k=1, we have constant returns to scale If k<1, we have decreasing returns to scale If k>1, we have increasing returns to scale

31 Elasticity of Substitution
The elasticity of substitution () measures the proportionate change in K/L relative to the proportionate change in the RTS along an isoquant The value of  will always be positive because K/L and RTS move in the same direction

32 Elasticity of Substitution
Both RTS and K/L will change as we move from point A to point B A B  is the ratio of these proportional changes K per period  measures the curvature of the isoquant RTSA RTSB (K/L)A (K/L)B q = q0 L per period

33 Elasticity of Substitution
If  is high, the RTS will not change much relative to K/L the isoquant will be relatively flat If  is low, the RTS will change by a substantial amount as K/L changes the isoquant will be sharply curved It is possible for  to change along an isoquant or as the scale of production changes

34 The Linear Production Function
Suppose that the production function is q = f(K,L) = aK + bL This production function exhibits constant returns to scale f(mK,mL) = amK + bmL = m(aK + bL) = mf(K,L) All isoquants are straight lines RTS is constant  = 

35 The Linear Production Function
Capital and labor are perfect substitutes K per period RTS is constant as K/L changes slope = -b/a q1 q2 q3  =  L per period

36 Fixed Proportions Suppose that the production function is
q = min (aK,bL) a,b > 0 Capital and labor must always be used in a fixed ratio the firm will always operate along a ray where K/L is constant Because K/L is constant,  = 0

37 Fixed Proportions No substitution between labor and capital is possible K/L is fixed at b/a q3/b q3/a K per period q1 q2 q3  = 0 L per period

38 Cobb-Douglas Production Function
Suppose that the production function is q = f(K,L) = AKaLb A,a,b > 0 This production function can exhibit any returns to scale f(mK,mL) = A(mK)a(mL) b = Ama+b KaLb = ma+bf(K,L) if a + b = 1  constant returns to scale if a + b > 1  increasing returns to scale if a + b < 1  decreasing returns to scale

39 Cobb-Douglas Production Function
Suppose that hamburgers are produced according to the Cobb-Douglas function q = 10K 0.5 L0.5 Since a+b=1  constant returns to scale The isoquant map can be derived q = 50 = 10K 0.5 L0.5  KL = 25 q = 100 = 10K 0.5 L0.5  KL = 100 The isoquants are rectangular hyperbolas

40 Cobb-Douglas Production Function
The RTS can easily be calculated The RTS declines as L rises and K falls The RTS depends only on the ratio of K and L Because the RTS changes exactly in proportion to changes in K/L,  = 1

41 Cobb-Douglas Production Function
The Cobb-Douglas production function is linear in logarithms ln q = ln A + a ln K + b ln L a is the elasticity of output with respect to K b is the elasticity of output with respect to L

42 CES Production Function
Suppose that the production function is q = f(K,L) = [K + L] /   1,   0,  > 0  > 1  increasing returns to scale  < 1  decreasing returns to scale For this production function  = 1/(1-)  = 1  linear production function  = -  fixed proportions production function  = 0  Cobb-Douglas production function

43 Technical Progress Methods of production change over time
Following the development of superior production techniques, the same level of output can be produced with fewer inputs the isoquant shifts in

44 Technical Progress Suppose that the production function is
q = A(t)f(K,L) where A(t) represents all influences that go into determining q other than K and L changes in A over time represent technical progress A is shown as a function of time (t) dA/dt > 0

45 Technical Progress Differentiating the production function with respect to time we get

46 Technical Progress Dividing by q gives us

47 Technical Progress For any variable x, [(dx/dt)/x] is the proportional growth rate in x denote this by Gx Then, we can write the equation in terms of growth rates

48 Technical Progress Since

49 Technical Progress in the Cobb-Douglas Function
Suppose that the production function is q = 10e 0.05t K 0.5 L0.5 Taking logarithms yields ln q = ln t ln K ln L Differentiating with respect to t gives the growth equation

50 Technical Progress in the Cobb-Douglas Function
We can put this in terms of growth rates Gq = GK + 0.5GL When K and L are constant, output grows at 5 percent per period GK = GL = 0 Gq = 0.05

51 Important Points to Note:
If all but one of the inputs are held constant, a relationship between the single variable input and output can be derived the marginal physical productivity is the change in output resulting from a one-unit increase in the use of the input the marginal physical productivity of an input is assumed to decline as use of the input increases

52 Important Points to Note:
The entire production function can be illustrated by an isoquant map The slope of an isoquant is the marginal rate of technical substitution RTS measures how one input can be substituted for another while holding output constant RTS is the ratio of the marginal physical productivities of the two inputs Isoquants are assumed to be convex they obey the assumption of a diminishing RTS

53 Important Points to Note:
The returns to scale exhibited by a production function record how output responds to proportionate increases in all inputs if output increases proportionately with input use, there are constant returns to scale if there are greater than proportionate increases in output, there are increasing returns to scale if there are less than proportionate increases in output, there are decreasing returns to scale

54 Important Points to Note:
The elasticity of substitution () provides a measure of how easy it is to substitute on input for another in production a high  implies nearly straight isoquants a low  implies that isoquants are nearly L-shaped Technical progress shifts the entire production function and isoquant map may arise from the use of more productive inputs or better economic organization


Download ppt "BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google