Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Economics of International Financial Policy: ITF 220

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Economics of International Financial Policy: ITF 220"— Presentation transcript:

1 Economics of International Financial Policy: ITF 220
Staff -- Professor: Jeffrey Frankel , Littauer 217 Office hours: Mondays 4:15-5:15; Tuesdays 2:00-3: Faculty Asst.: Minoo Ghoreishi, Belfer 505 (617) Teaching Fellow: Tilahun Emiru Course Assistant: Jing Zhao Times – Lectures: Mon. & Wed., 2:40-4:00 p.m., L382 Review session: Fri.10:10-11: Mt.Auburn, suite 160, rm.105. Final exam: Monday, May 12, 2014, 2:00-5:00 p.m. Requirements -- Textbook: World Trade & Payments + Readings. 6 Problem Sets (20%) + Midterm (30%) + Final exam (50%) .

2 Big topics covered in the course
I) ELASTICITIES & THE TRADE BALANCE II) THE KEYNESIAN MODEL OF INCOME THE MONETARY APPROACH TO THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS IV) GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCIAL MARKETS V) FISCAL & MONETARY POLICY UNDER INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY VI) INTERDEPENDENCE AND COORDINATION VII) SUPPLY, INFLATION & MONETARY UNION VIII) EXPECTATIONS, MONEY, & DETERMINATION OF THE EXCHANGE RATE Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

3 TOPIC I: ELASTICITIES & THE TRADE BALANCE
Lecture 1: Balance of Payments Accounting Lecture 2: Supply & demand for foreign exchange; export and import elasticities Lecture 3: Empirical effects of devaluation on the trade balance

4 Lecture 1: Balance of payments accounting
Definition: The balance of payments is the year’s record of economic transactions between domestic and foreign residents. The rules: If you have to pay a foreign resident, normally in exchange for something that you bring into the country, then the something counts as a debit. If a foreign resident has to pay you for something, then the something counts as a credit. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

5 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
† Now also called “financial account” Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

6 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
PER QUARTER Measures of external balance US Current Account Goods & Services Goods US services surplus partially offsets the deficit in goods. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

7 Examples on the current account:
You, an American, import software CD-roms from India => debits appear on US merchandise account. You import services (electronically) of an Indian software firm => debit appears on US services account. (This is the famous and controversial “overseas outsourcing.”) You buy the services, instead, from a subsidiary that the Indian software firm set up last year in the US. This is not an international transaction, and so does not appear in the accounts. But assume the subsidiary sends some profits back to India => debit appears on US investment income account. (It is as if the US is paying for the services of Indian capital.) Employees of the subsidiary in the US (or any other US resident entities) send money to relatives back in India => debit appears under unilateral transfers. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

8 Examples on the long-term capital account:
Instead of buying software CD-roms from India, you buy the company in India that makes them. => debit appears on US capital account, under FDI. (You have imported ownership of the company.) Instead of buying the entire company in India, you buy some stock in it => debit appears on US capital account, under equities. (You have imported claims against an Indian resident.) Instead of buying stock in the company, you lend it money for 2 years => debit appears on US capital account, under bonds or bank loans. (Again, you have imported a claim against an Indian resident.) Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

9 Examples on the short-term capital account:
You lend to the Indian company in the form of 30-day commercial paper or trade credit => debit appears on US short-term capital account. (Again, you have acquired a claim against India.) You lend to the Indian company in the form of cash dollars, which they don’t have to pay back for 30 days => debit appears on US short-term capital account. You are the Central Bank, and you buy securities of the Indian company (an improbable example for the Fed – but “Sovereign Wealth Funds,” from China to oil-exporting countries, now make international investments of this sort) => debit appears as a US official reserves transaction. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

10 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
The rules, continued Each transaction is recorded twice: once as a credit and once as a debit. E.g., when an importer pays cash dollars, the debit on the merchandise account is offset by a credit under short-term capital: the exporter in the other country has, at least for the moment, increased holdings of US assets, which counts as a credit just like any other portfolio investment in US assets. At the end of each quarter, credits & debits are added up within each line-item; and line-items are cumulated from the top to compute measures of external balance. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

11 Some balance of payments identities
CA ≡ Rate of increase in net international investment position. CA-surplus country (Japan) accumulates claims against foreigners; CA-deficit country (US) borrows from foreigners. CA + KA + ORT ≡ 0 . BoP ≡ CA + KA . => BoP ≡ -ORT ≡ excess supply of FX coming from private sector, (i.e., all credits from exports of goods, services, assets… minus all debits) which central banks absorb into reserves, if they intervene in FX market). A BoP surplus country (China, Saudi A.) adds to its FX reserves A BoP deficit country (Argentina) either runs down its FX reserves or, is lucky enough for foreign central banks to finance the deficit, if its currency is an international reserve asset (US $) . A floating country (Japan, Chile) does not intervene in the FX market => BP ≡ 0; Exchange rate E adjusts to clear FX supply & demand in private market

12 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
End of Lecture 1: Balance of Payments Accounting Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

13 Lecture 2: The Elasticities Approach to the Trade Balance
Primary question: Under what circumstances does devaluation improve the trade balance (TB), and how much? Secondary question: If the currency floats (i.e., the central bank does not intervene in the foreign exchange market), how much must the exchange rate (E) move to clear the trade balance by itself ? Model: Elasticities Approach Key equation: Marshall-Lerner Condition Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

14 Supply & demand for foreign exchange
D S E ≡ price of foreign exchange in $/₤ FX supply arises from exports, capital inflows… FX demand arises from imports, capital outflows… Quantity of foreign exchange, ₤ Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

15 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
Assume demand for forex shifts out e.g., to due to increase in demand to buy foreign goods or assets Deficit (excess demand for foreign currency) Depreciation (increase in price of foreign currency) Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

16 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
The Elasticities Approach to the Trade Balance derives the supply of foreign exchange from export earnings, and derives the demand for foreign exchange from import spending. Capital flows are not considered (until later), so no supply of, or demand for, FX comes from international borrowing or lending. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

17 How the Exchange Rate, E, Influences BoP
ASSUMPTIONS : Supply of FX determined by EXPORT earnings Demand for FX determined by IMPORT spending No capital flows or transfers => BoP = TB 2) PCP: Price in terms of producer’s currency; Supply elasticity = ∞ . => Domestic firms set . & Foreign firms set 3) Complete exchange rate passthrough: Price of X in foreign currency = / E Price of Imports in domestic currency = E 4) Demand is a decreasing function of price in consumer’s currency => X = XD ( / E ) . => IM= IMD (E ) . => Net supply of FX = TB expressed in foreign currency ≡ TB* = ( /E) XD( /E) ( ) IMD(E ) . Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

18 How the TB is affected by the exchange rate (continued)
TRADE BALANCE EXPRESSED IN FOREIGN CURRENCY TB* = ( /E) XD( /E) ( ) IMD(E ) . EXPERIMENT : E↑ THREE EFFECTS (1) IMD( ) falls. EFFECT ON TB* + - (2) XD( ) rises. (3) Price of X in terms of foreign currency falls. NET EFFECT ON TB* is determined by Marshall-Lerner condition. Add one more assumption: Before the devaluation, TB*=0, so export earnings cancel out import spending, Then devaluation improves the TB iff: εX + εM > 1 .

19 Example (i) to illustrate Marshall-Lerner condition
for TB* = ( /E) XD( /E) - ( ) IMD(E ) If εx =1, then E ↑ leaves export revenue unchanged. Because effects (2) and (3) cancel out. In that case, so long as εM > 0, Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied: Import spending falls -- effect (1) -- TB* improves. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

20 Example (ii) to illustrate Marshall-Lerner condition
for TB* = ( /E) XD( /E) - ( ) IMD(E ) . If εx = 0, then E ↑ cuts export revenue in proportion because of valuation effect (3) In that case, is εM > 1 necessary to improve TB* ? Yes, because of Marshall-Lerner condition -- fall in import spending then outweighs fall in export revenue: effect (1) > effect (2) -- provided initial X revenue > import spending. But if initial TB*<0, elasticities need not be as high. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

21 How the TB is affected by the exchange rate (continued)
TRADE BALANCE EXPRESSED IN DOMESTIC CURRENCY TB = ( ) XD( /E) (E ) IMD(E ) . EXPERIMENT : E↑ THREE EFFECTS (2) IMD( ) falls. EFFECT ON TB + - (1) XD( ) rises. (3) Price of IMports in terms of domestic currency rises. NET EFFECT ON TB is determined by the same Marshall-Lerner condition. Again, assume that initially TB=0. Then devaluation improves the TB iff: εX + εM > 1 .

22 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
End of Lecture 2: Elasticities Approach to the Trade Balance Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

23 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
Lecture 3: Empirical effects of devaluation on the trade balance Examples: Italy after 1992; Poland after 2008. Elasticity Pessimism: • Countries often fear their elasticities are too low for the M-L condition. Econometric estimation of elasticities • What is OLS regression? • Typical estimates • The importance of lags. The J-curve • With fast pass-through to import prices • With slow pass-through to import prices . Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

24 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
1992 devaluation Rise in trade balance Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

25 Poland’s exchange rate rose 35% in the 2008-09 global crisis.
Depreciation boosted net exports => Poland avoided recession, alone in EU Exchange rate Zloty / € Contribution of Net X in 2009: % of GDP > Total GDP growth: 1.7% Source: Cezary Wójcik

26 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
How can we estimate sensitivity of export demand to exchange rate? OLS regression X ≡ Exports demanded EP*/P ≡ Price of foreign goods relative to domestic goods Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

27 Common econometric finding
Estimated trade elasticities with respect to relative prices often ≈ 1, after a few years have been allowed to pass. => Marshall-Lerner condition holds in the medium run. Some face a higher elasticity of demand for their exports: small countries, and producers of agricultural & mineral commodities or other commodities that are close substitutes for competitors’ exports.

28 Common empirical observation:
After a devaluation, trade balance gets worse before it gets better. Explanation: Even if devaluation is instantly passed through to higher import prices, buyers react with a lag. Also, in practice, it often takes time before the devaluation is passed through to import prices.

29 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
End of Lecture 3: Empirical Effects of Devaluation on the Trade Balance Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

30 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
Appendix: Determinants of US TB 1980 deficits: Effects of $ appreciation of (“Reaganomics”) $ depreciation of (Plaza Accord). Subsequent deficits: Effects of $ appreciation of Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

31 Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University
US TB & CA, , $ millions The deficits shrank sharply in , due to: lagged effects of $ depreciation and the recession. Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Kennedy School, Harvard University

32 US trade and current account balances 1970-2010
($ millions) ↑ Surplus ↓ Deficit Services always partially offset the deficit in goods. The US trade balance was on a downward trend, despite a few temporary improvements (including during recessions: , 2001, & especially ) Professor Jeffrey Frankel, Harvard University


Download ppt "Economics of International Financial Policy: ITF 220"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google