Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Equilibrium Asset Pricing
Michael J. Brennan June 2008
2
Three standard assumptions
Market prices are efficient Prices are set by rational expected utility maximizing individuals Returns are serially independent
3
Asset Pricing and Mispricing
Three papers Asset Pricing and Mispricing With Ashley Wang Agency and Asset Pricing With Feifei Li Work in progess
4
A. Market prices are efficient
5
Unconditional Rational Prices inconsistent with Unconditional Rational Expected Returns
Unconditional rational prices with random mispricing: Proof:
6
A Basic Result If mispricing is uncorrelated with fundamentals, and
prices are unconditionally rational, then: Expected returns exceed rational expected returns – a mispricing return premium:
7
A Simple Example Perpetual bond with coupon $4 and market interest rate 4%: P* = 100 Bond trades at 90, 100, 110
8
A Simple Example Annual Transition probabilities
Steady state probabilities Expected Price: 100 (Unconditional rational pricing) Expected rate of return 4.42% 90 100 110 0.05 0.9 0.3 0.4 0.90 0.20 0.60
9
A More General Model Ignoring dividends: Neglecting dividends
10
Components of Return Bias, B = B1 + B2
B2 > 0 Over-reaction B2 < 0 Under-reaction Assuming z is stationary
11
Empirical Analysis Mispricing model Data AR1: Kalman filter estimates
NYSE/AMEX/Nasdaq stocks January 1962-Dec 2004
12
AR1 Mispricing Estimates
Each January from 1967 to 2004 KF used to estimate mispricing return bias from FF3 residuals (e) over previous 60 months assuming AR1 model: Assumes mispricing uncorrelated with fundamentals: FF3 + εt
19
Are returns related to our empirical estimate of ‘theoretical return bias’ B1 ?
20
10 Portfolios formed in January of each year
Based on estimates of B1 Equally weighted and not rebalanced during year Estimated MRP of portfolios runs from 14bp to 6% p.a. High bias portfolios Higher No difference in Firms with highest fundamental volatility have most mispricing Portfolio NCV: median size; lower than median beta_HML; close to median beta_SMB and beta_MKT; close to median raw returns and FF3 alphas
21
Annualized FF3 alphas and Bias Estimates January 1967 to December 2004
z ranges from 1.08% to 16.70% Difference (Hi-Lo) = 8.64% p.a. t-stat(Hi-Lo) = 3.25
22
Conclusions A mean zero stochastic mispricing error can drive expected return away from fundamental return Lower For mispricing independent of fundamentals, more transient and volatile mispricing leads to bigger return premium Slow adjustment to information can potentially explain very high liquidity premium since illiquid stocks are those most subject to mispricing
23
B. Prices are set by rational expected utility maximizing individuals
24
Agency and Asset Pricing
CAPM with Individual mean-variance investors Agents also mean-variance but with respect to return relative to (individual) benchmark portfolio Equilibrium Two beta ‘capm’ market beta – positive risk premium (aggregate) benchmark beta – negative risk premium
25
betas w.r.t market and ‘benchmark residual
Note: the benchmark portfolio is ‘riskless asset’ for agents different agents may have different benchmarks – ‘aggregate benchmark portfolio’
26
Empirical Analysis Form 25 value weighted portfolios in January each year from 1931 to 2006 based on: CRSP value market weighted beta beta w.r.t. S&P500 (residual) Hold for 1 year without rebalancing Calculate alphas of linked returns F-M analysis to track rewards to market and S&P500 (residual) betas
28
The agency induced benchmark effect is:
Confined to large firms and shows up only in value weighted portfolios Correlation between proportional institutional ownership and log firm size is 0.63 (Gompers and Metrick, 2001) Confined to post 1970 period ‘in recent years risk-adjusted measures of performance have been receiving considerable attention outside the academic journals.. Bank Administration Institute study of complete evaluation must include an assessment of risk….SEC Study of performance measures must be adjusted for volatility..’ (Klemkosky, 1973)
32
The results (for value weighted portfolios) are robust to measurement wrt FF 3-factor model
34
Conclusion Significant agency/benchmark effect Starts from around 1970
Only apparent for large firms Robust to FF 3-factor model
35
C. Security Returns are iid
One period expected return is sufficient statistic for n period expected return Risk should be measured using one period returns How long is ‘period’ Instantaneous – Merton (1971) One month (CRSP)
36
First order autocorrelations of 25 FF Size and B/M portfolios July 1926- February 2006
37
Effect of autocorrelation on n-period expected returns
Annualized n month returns: Independent of n if returns iid
38
Standardized annualized returns on FF 25 portfolios as a function of the holding period, n
39
Expected returns vary with holding period
Do betas also vary with holding period?
40
Betas of FF 25 portfolios as function of holding period
41
Standardized betas as a function of the holding period (months) for FF25 portfolios 1926-2006
42
The issue At what frequency (if any) do we expect CAPM to hold?
High frequency if low transaction costs Low frequency if high transaction costs High and low frequency ?? An empirical issue!
43
Cross-section regressions for n month returns
44
Annualized lam_0 for different holding periods for FF 25 portfolios 1926-2006
45
Scaled Empirical Market Price of Risk as a function of holding period
46
RSQ from Cross Section Regression as function of holding period (months)
47
The 1 month CAPM
48
The 12 month CAPM
49
Conclusion Single period of CAPM is arbitrary Returns are not iid
Betas and expected returns both depend on holding period ‘Fit’ of CAPM improves with assumed holding period
50
Summary Random mispricing affects (risk-adjusted) average returns
Average returns affected by agency/benchmark effects Returns not iid Expected returns and betas depend on holding period Fit of CAPM improves with assumed holding period
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.