Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byKelly Martin Modified over 6 years ago
1
Clean energy in Thailand: Potential, Planning and Policy
Asia Regional Energy Trend Seminar 8 November 2004 Platani Resort & Spa, Rayong – Thailand Chris Greacen Palang Thai Notes – I’m going to talk about
2
Outline Context Potential Planning Policy Actual vs. potential
Conventional approach Integrated Resource Planning (IRP) Risk Policy Access Tariff
3
Context – the electricity supply industry in Thailand
SPPs (11%) EGAT (51%) EGCO (10%) RATCH (16%) IPPs (10%) Import (2%) Generaration (% capacity) Self regulated monopolies Transmission EGAT (100%) Distribution PEA (63%) MEA (35%) Direct Customers (2%) Thailand’s power sector is composed of self regulated state-owned monopolies. Gen is dominated by EGAT + subsideraries EGCO & RATCH. Trans is 100% EGAT. Dist is dominated by MEA & PEA. Little intererest in splitting trans & gen, or in forming regulatory body. Users Users
4
Clean energy potential
Actual vs. potential Renewables DSM Cogeneration
5
Estimate of installed grid-connected renewables in Thailand (2004)
Resource Capacity (MW) Biogas 7 Biomass 215 (to grid) (not including 419 MW self-gen) Small & micro-hydro 139 Solar PV 1.2 Wind 0.7 TOTAL 363 Source: 2003 Thai government figures + updates for biogas & PV based on recent installations
6
Renewables account for very little of Thailands’ installed generating capacity
0.6% จากพลังงานหมุนเวียน Big hydro 0.6% grid-connected renewables lignite Fuel oil Natural gas TOTAL: 26,000 MW Source: EGAT (2003). Power Development Plan
7
Estimated renewable energy potential in Thailand
Resource Technical potential (MW) Commerical Potential (MW) Year 2011 Government targets (MW) Biomass (includes biogas) Solar PV Wind Micro- & Mini- hydro 7,000 >5,000 1,600 700 >4,500 ? 350? 1140 250 100 350 Total >14,000 >4,800 1840 Biomass commercially viable 3727 MW (from Black & Veatch 2000 and NEPO/DANCED 1998) as well as interviews with power plant managers. Biogas additional = 385. Source: Technical potential and Targets from Thai Ministry of Energy. (2003).“Energy Strategy for Competitiveness” Commercial potential from from Black & Veatch 2000 and NEPO/DANCED 1998 as well as interviews with power plant managers.
8
Breakdown of economically viable biomass resource
Economic potential (MW) Bagasse 2,500 Wood residues 950 Rice husk 500 Biogas (cassava, pig, food waste) 385 Corncob 54 Distillery slop 49 Coconut 43 Palm oil residues TOTAL 4,524 Source: Black and Veatch (2000). Final Report: Thailand Biomass-Based Power Generation and Cogeneration Within Small Rural Industries. Bangkok, NEPO; NEPO/DANCED (1998). Investigation of Pricing Incentive in a Renewable Energy Strategy -- Main report. Bangkok. Bagasse figure from interview with interview with Sirisak Tatong, power plant manager at Mitr Phol sugar factory. Biogas from interviews with biogas developers
9
Technology is available…
Steam turbines for direct combustion of biomass Rice husk, wood chip, palm husk, bagasse, coconut husk, etc. Size >1 MW Capital cost $1200/kW Commercially available in Thailand Bio-digestors & engines for biogas Pig manure, cassava, palm oil, municipal wastes, distillery slop Size > 30 kW Problems with SO2 resolvable Gasifiers Rice husk, wood chip Size > 50 kW. Problems with tar in some fuels Commercially available for wood chip
10
Biogas from Pig Farms Reduces air and water pollution
Produces fertilizer Produces electricity Biogas from Pig Farms
11
Biogas from Pig Farms As of Jan 2004: 4 farms legally connected
Potential for hundreds of farms 5000 pigs $31 / day elec.
12
100 kW Wind turbine Part of environmental training center
ReCycle Engineering, Chonburi
13
Community micro-hydro
Mae Kam Pong village, Chiang Mai 40 kW Community cooperative Expected gross revenues: 30,000 baht/month
14
40 kW micro-hydro generator at Mae Kam Pong
00-
15
Korat Waste to Energy - biogas
Uses waste water from cassava Removes 99% of COD Produces gas for all factory heat + 5 MW of electricity
16
Korat Waste to Energy - biogas
3 x 1 MW Jenbacher gas generators
17
DSM + Cogeneration potential even bigger
2000 to 3000 MW: “Achievable and cost effective DSM” in 1991 (Utility study) IIEC (International Institute for Energy Conservation) Demand Side Management for Thailand’s Electric Power System: Five-Year Master Plan. Submitted to Electricity Generating Authority of Thailand, Metropolitan Electricity Authority and Provincial Electricity Authority, Bangkok, Thailand. Bangkok, Thailand. November. Cogeneration 8610 MW cogen installed as of 2001 Since 1998, utilities accepting no new cogen. At least 3,000 MW of additional cogen had applied and have not been accepted. No systematic evaluation since 1991.
18
Planning Conventional approach Integrated Resource Planning (IRP) Risk
19
Conventional planning approach
Demand forecast – determined by committee comprising mainly government (EPPO), and utilities (EGAT,MEA, PEA) Power Development Plan (PDP) -- Developed by EGAT.
20
Conventional approach step #1: Demand forecasts (vs. actual demand)
Do they overestimate? Yes, they do!
21
Correcting some blatant errors in conventional process…
6.5% growth figure from govt (for first 5 years). From 5 to 15th year, hired consultant – TDRI.
22
Conventional planning problems
Process Problem Citizens and consumers have no role in decisions No consideration of alternatives: Renewables DSM Cogeneration No accountability to ensure that the plan is appropriate or least-cost EGAT Peak demand +15% reserve = minimum generating capacity Specify new generators & transmission (PDP) Only considers gas/coal/big hydro Ministry of Energy endorses plan NEPC Approve Cabinet Acknowledge
23
Conventional approach step #2: Power development plan
Generation capacity = peak demand + 15% Note, 15% reserve margin may have made sense when whole sys was smaller. But with bigger system, the impact of losing one power plant is lower.
24
Problems Little transparency Little accountability
Little participation No consideration of alternatives DSM Cogeneration Renewables
25
Integrated Resource Planning (IRP) – a way forward?
Integrated Resource Planning (IRP or least cost planning) has origins in the 1980’s. The principle of IRP is that customers do not actually need kWh, instead they require the services that are provided by electricity: “warm houses, light, and cold beer”. Note – focus is on consumers needs for energy services, not simply kWh of supply.
26
Integrated Resource Planning (IRP) – what is it?
Services can either be met by building new power plants, or by increasing efficiency of use. IRP is a systematic planning framework to meet consumers needs for energy services in a way that best meets multiple objectives for resource use Requires consideration of energy demand, energy supply, environment, costs, and other factors all together An integrated resource plan states a utility’s preferred strategy for meeting consumers’ needs over the long term—for example, 20 years Goal of IRP: develop plans to meet energy needs of society efficiently, and at lowest possible cost Note – focus is on consumers needs for energy services, not simply kWh of supply.
27
Overview of the IRP Process: Introduction
#
28
Risk and ‘Mean Variance Portfolio Theory’
Fossil fuel prices are volatile Fossil fuels are negatively correlated to macroeconomic activity Mean Variance Theory (Harry Markowitz, Nobel Prize 1954): “adding bonds and other low-risk investments enhances portfolio performance over time because annual returns move independently.”
29
Risk and Return for Portfolios of Risky Assets
30
Wind/RE Lowers Mexico Generating Cost
31
Challenge… How to strategically push planning to include:
Greater transparency, accountability, and participation (TAP) Real inclusion of alternatives in ways that address risk and environmental benefits of these technologies DSM Renewables Cogen
32
Policy Grid Access for renewables 4 recommendations
33
POLICY RECOMMENDATION 1.
There must be a fully independent and empowered electricity regulatory authority. The regulator’s responsibilities should include reducing costs and determining tariffs, ensuring system reliability and energy security (including reducing the use of imported fuels), as well as coming up with effective mechanisms to reduce greenhouse gases and implement the government policy of promoting clean, renewable energy.
34
POLICY RECOMMENDATION 2
MEA and PEA should be responsible for purchasing their own power, rather than having the responsibility for bulk power supply provision lie entirely with EGAT. Currently SPPs connect through PEA and MEA lines, but they sign power purchase agreements with EGAT. But EGAT, as a generator itself, has incentives to discourage competitor generators. Instead, MEA and PEA should be allowed to purchase power from wherever they wish. This would simplify the bureaucratic process and give MEA and PEA more incentives to favor small, decentralized generation located near loads.
35
POLICY RECOMMENDATION 3.
Power generation and supply companies should have no ownership or management interest in the transmission system. The current situation in which EGAT is both owner and operator of the transmission system, as well as a generator of electricity raises the suspicion that non-EGAT parties may face discrimination in access to the grid. Separating transmission from other parts of the system is vital for the simple reason that unreasonable network pricing or access constraints can be used as a highly effective tool to discourage competition from other generators and/or suppliers of electricity.
36
POLICY RECOMMENDATION 4
All generators of electricity should have fair and non-discriminatory access to the grid. The regulator must restrain Thai utilities from outrageous charges, unreasonable technical stipulations, or inexplicable delays in processing paperwork. Without straightforward and fair (to both distributed electricity developer and network operator) procedures for enabling access, distributed renewable energy can never flourish.
37
Download this presentation at:
For more information Contact: Tel Download this presentation at:
38
Adding Wind to EU Generating Mix Lowers Cost and Risk
Generating Costs (Euro Cents) (Source: IEA, 2001) GAS: / kWh COAL: / kWh WIND: / kWh
40
POLICY RECOMMENDATION 5
Feed-in tariffs are more appropriate for Thailand than RPS for grid-connected renewable energy. current plans call for an RPS to achieve renewables targets. international experience: RPS without an independent regulatory body is problematic. An independent and empowered agency (other than the soon-to-be partially privatized monopoly utility, EGAT) is needed to ensure that procurement of renewable energy is fair – especially since EGAT will be able to pass costs directly to consumers. An approach more suitable for Thailand's weak regulatory environment is to use feed-in tariffs as is done in Germany, Denmark, Spain and China. This approach promises lower barriers to entry to smaller renewable energy companies because it is simpler and entails less risk to renewable energy producers, and better enables the harnessing of Thailand's significant cost-effective distributed biomass waste resources.
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.