Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
1
Market equilibrium
2
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Announcement I somehow got one lecture ahead of schedule Will modify syllabus Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
3
Economic Surplus in the Market for Milk
Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day) Price ($/gallon) 1 .50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Producer surplus = $4,000/day S D Consumer surplus=$2000/day Economic surplus = consumer surplus + producer surplus Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
4
Market Equilibrium and Efficiency
In theory, market equilibriums maximize economic surplus What do you think? Is maximizing economic surplus an appropriate desirable end? Is it the sole desirable end? Is maximizing surplus equitable? Demand=preferences weighted by income Do markets move toward equilibrium? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
5
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
6
Housing prices: Equilibrium?
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
7
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
What is efficiency? Are markets efficient? Measures of efficiency for food systems What is the desirable end? What is the input? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
8
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
What is efficiency? The Economists view: Pareto efficiency A situation in which there are no transactions available that would make at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off. Also called Pareto optimality Different from productive efficiency, i.e. attaining a point on the PPF Pareto efficiency implies productive efficiency, but not vice versa Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
9
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Think about it: Would it be efficient if Bill Gates owned everything in the world? Would it be optimal? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
10
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Efficiency and equity Pareto efficiency and Diminishing marginal utility What’s worth more, $1000 to a rich person or a poor person? 300 calories to a Zambian or an American? What makes a greater contribution to happiness? To social welfare? Should society value an increase in wealth for the poor more than an equal increase for the rich? What’s actually been happening? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
11
Market Equilibrium and Efficiency
A market equilibrium is Pareto efficient If price and quantity take any other than their equilibrium values, a transaction that will make at least some people better off without harming others can always be found. 1st fundamental theorem of welfare economics: Any market equilibrium is Pareto efficient Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
12
Market Equilibrium and Efficiency
A market equilibrium is Pareto efficient BUT prices are determined by demand, and demand is preferences weighted by wealth and income There is a different Pareto efficient outcome for every initial distribution of wealth and income The desirability of the outcome is determined by the desirability of the distribution that gave rise to it. 2nd fundamental theorem of welfare economics: we can achieve any Pareto equilibrium through lump sum transfers Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
13
How do we choose between Pareto efficient outcomes?
TWO NEOCLASSICAL ANSWERS: We don’t in which case the efficient market equilibrium is no more optimal than the distribution of resources that produced it. Potential Pareto Optimality We choose the outcome which could be a Pareto optimum if the winners compensated the losers, i.e. whatever produces most wealth Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
14
How do we choose between Pareto efficient outcomes?
ONE EE ANSWER: We solve the distribution problem before we let markets allocate Just distribution takes precedence over efficient allocation Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
15
A Market in Which Price Is Below the Equilibrium Level
D S 2.50 2.00 1.50 Price ($/gallon) 1.00 .50 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day) Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
16
Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day)
How Excess Demand Creates an Opportunity for a Surplus-Enhancing Transaction 2.50 Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day) Price ($/gallon) D S 1 2 3 4 5 2.00 1.50 1.00 .50 1.25 If P = $1 then QS = 2,000 gallons/day At 2,000 gallons the consumer is willing to pay $2 and the MC = $1 If the buyer pays $1.25 for an extra gallon, producer is $.25 better off, and the consumer is $.75 better off, or economic surplus increases by $1.00 At $1, the market is not efficient Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
17
Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day)
How Excess Supply Creates an Opportunity for a Surplus-Enhancing Transaction Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day) Price ($/gallon) D S 1 2 3 4 5 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 .50 1.75 If P = $2 then QD = 2,000 gallons/day Additional output costs only $1 This is $1 less than a buyer would pay If the buyer pays the seller $1.75, the buyer gains an economic surplus of $0.25 then the seller gains an economic surplus of $0.75 Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
18
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
If the price of a resource is above or below the equilibrium quantity, which of the following is true? The quantity exchanged will be less than the equilibrium quantity There is an opportunity to increase economic surplus The value on the demand curve (MB) is greater than the value on the supply curve (MC) at that quantity. Pareto improvements are possible All of the above Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
19
Markets will only be efficient when
Buyers and sellers are well informed. How often is this the case? NYT: Banks That Bundled Bad Debt Also Bet Against It What happens as the number of goods proliferates? Markets are perfectly competitive Vs. too big to fail Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
20
Markets will only be efficient when
Supply measures all relevant costs and benefits. Laws of thermodynamics Outsourcing How do we measure these costs? Demand measures all relevant benefits and costs. NYT Income Inequality: Too Big to Ignore by R. Frank “The rich have been spending more simply because they have so much extra money. Their spending shifts the frame of reference...[which make] it substantially more expensive for middle-class families to achieve basic financial goals” Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
21
Market Equilibrium and Efficiency
What do you think? Is efficiency the only goal? Should efficiency be the first goal? Is efficiency possible? Most textbooks explicitly state that efficiency is the desirable end Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
22
The Cost of Preventing Price Adjustments
Price Ceilings: Do They Help the Poor? An Example: a Price Ceiling for Home Heating Oil Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
23
Economic Surplus in an Unregulated Market for Home Heating Oil
Producer surplus = $900/day Consumer surplus = $900/day 2.00 D S 1.80 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 Without price controls: Equilibrium Price = $1.40 Consumer surplus = (1/2)(3,000)(.60) = $900/day Producer surplus = (1/2)(3,000)(.6) = 900/day Economic surplus = $1,800/day Price ($/gallon) .80 1 2 3 4 5 8 Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day) Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
24
The Waste Caused by Price Controls
Price Ceiling set at $1.00 S 2.00 Consumer surplus = $900/day 1.80 Lost economic surplus = $800/day 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 Producer surplus = $100/day D Price ($/gallon) .80 With price controls: Producer surplus = (1/2)(1,000)(.20) = $100/day or a loss of $800/day Economic surplus = $1,000 or a loss of $800/day 1 2 3 4 5 8 Quantity (1,000s of gallons/day) Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
25
The Cost of Preventing Price Adjustments
Conventional economists say the reduction in economic surplus from a price ceiling will be underestimated when The consumers who receive the product are not the consumers who value it the most. BUT demand is most inelastic for the wealthiest consumers Consumers take costly actions to enhance their chances of being served. Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
26
The Cost of Preventing Price Adjustments
Question What programs could be used to help the poor get heating oil that would be more efficient than a price ceiling? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
27
When the Pie Is Larger, Everyone Can Have a Bigger Slice
Surplus with price controls Surplus with income transfers and no price controls With price controls set at $1.00 the economic surplus is $1,000/day *R = economic surplus received by rich people *P = economic surplus received by poor people Without price controls & with income transfers economic surplus is $1,800/day *R & P have the same share and a much larger economic surplus Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
28
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Rationing In WWII, everyone received a coupon for how much heating oil they could consume. Rationing was the solution Brazil used for it’s recent energy crisis. California just let prices soar. Coupons could be traded, going to the consumers that valued it most. Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
29
Other costs of adjustment
Question How politically feasible are income transfers relative to price ceilings or tradable ration coupons? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
30
The Cost of Preventing Price Adjustments
Price Subsidies: Do They Help the Poor? The view from mainstream economics By how much do subsidies reduce total economic surplus in the market for bread? Assume a small nation imports all its bread at the world price of $2.00 Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
31
The Reduction in Economic Surplus from a Subsidy
The cost of the subsidy = $6 million The benefit of the subsidy = $5 million Loss of economic surplus = $1 million 5.00 Consumer surplus = $9,000,000/month 4.00 Price of bread ($/loaf) Reduction in total economic surplus = $1,000,000/month 3.00 World price = $ 2.00 S 1.00 D 2 4 6 8 Quantity (millions of loaves/month Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
32
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
BUT… What’s the marginal utility of another loaf of bread to a family with malnourished children? What’s the future productivity of well-nourished children vs. malnourished ones? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
33
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
NYT Headlines: Ending Famine, Simply by Ignoring the Experts The secret of Malawi’s success: heavy subsidies for fertilizer, farmers say. The World Bank had pressed for their elimination. Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
34
Pricing of Public Services
Example How much should a city charge for water, electricity, or some other service essential to life? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
35
The Marginal Cost Curve for Water
4.0 0.8 0.2 1 3 Spring Lake Ocean Three sources of water Spring: 1 million gallons/day .02 cents/gallon Lake: 2 million .08 cents/gallon Ocean: 4 cents/gallon Cost (cents/gallon) Water supplied (millions of gallons/day) Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
36
The Marginal Cost Curve for Water
4.0 0.8 0.2 1 3 Spring Lake Ocean Assume If P = 4 cents/gallon, Q = 4 million gallons Question Why should all residents pay 4 cents per gallon? Cost (cents/gallon) Water supplied (millions of gallons/day) Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
37
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Mainstream view Price = marginal cost If price is less, people will use more, and cost of supplying more is 4 cents/gallon Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
38
Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
BUT… In Cochabamba, Bolivia, marginal pricing led to people spending 25% of income on water, rioting, and death. How much did Bolivia spend defending Bechtel’s profits? In South Africa, the rich fill their swimming pools, while the poor drink polluted water, and die of cholera What are the costs of cholera? Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
39
Commodity or human right?
Conventional economists look at almost everything as a commodity Can we distinguish by use? Water used for essential needs is a human right Water for non-essential uses is a commodity Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
40
Why not charge by quantity?
Cost of first 50 gallons/week (essential needs) = .02 cents/gallon Cost of next 100 gallons/week (important needs) =.08 cents/gallon All else costs 4 cents/gallon Chapter 7: Efficiency and Exchange
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.