Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byAlban Anderson Modified over 6 years ago
1
8th Granada Seminar – Modelling Complex Social Systems
On the evolutionary origins of altruistic behavior: can selection at the individual level be enough? José A. Cuesta & Anxo Sánchez GISC/Matemáticas Universidad Carlos III de Madrid
2
Cooperation: the basis of human societies
Anomaly in the animal world: Occurs between genetically unrelated individuals
3
Cooperation: the basis of human societies
Anomaly in the animal world: Shows high division of labor
4
Cooperation: the basis of human societies
Anomaly in the animal world: Valid for large scale organizations… …as well as hunter-gatherer groups
5
Cooperation: the basis of human societies
Anomaly in the animal world: Valid for large scale organizations… …or setting up nice events!
6
Cooperation: the basis of human societies
Some animals form complex societies… …but their individuals are genetically related
7
Altruism: key to cooperation
fitness-reducing act that benefits others Pure altruism is ruled out by natural selection acting on individuals á la Darwin
8
How did altruism arise? He who was ready to sacrifice his life (…), rather than betray his comrades, would often leave no offspring to inherit his noble nature… Therefore, it seems scarcely possible (…) that the number of men gifted with such virtues (…) would be increased by natural selection, that is, by the survival of the fittest. Charles Darwin (Descent of Man, 1871)
9
Altruism is an evolutionary puzzle
10
Group selection? Cultural evolution?
A man who was not impelled by any deep, instinctive feeling, to sacrifice his life for the good of others, yet was roused to such actions by a sense of glory, would by his example excite the same wish for glory in other men, and would strengthen by exercise the noble feeling of admiration. He might thus do far more good to his tribe than by begetting offsprings with a tendency to inherit his own high character. Charles Darwin (Descent of Man, 1871)
11
Answers to the puzzle… Kin cooperation (Hamilton, 1964)
common to animals and humans alike Reciprocal altruism in repeated interactions (Trivers, 1973; Axelrod & Hamilton, 1981) primates, specially humans Indirect reciprocity (reputation gain) (Nowak & Sigmund, 1998) None true altruism: individual benefits in the long run
12
… but only partial! Strong reciprocity (Gintis, 2000; Fehr, Fischbacher & Gächter, 2002) typically human (primates?) altruistic rewarding: predisposition to reward others for cooperative behavior altruistic punishment: propensity to impose sanctions on non-cooperators Strong reciprocators bear the cost of altruistic acts even if they gain no benefits Hammerstein (ed.), Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation (Dahlem Workshop Report 90, MIT, 2003)
13
Altruistic punishment: the Ultimatum Game
(Güth, Schmittberger & Schwarze, 1982) M euros M-u u experimenter OK NO u M-u proposer responder
14
Experimental results Responder’s optimal strategy: accept anything
Proposer’s optimal strategy: offer the minimum Results: Proposers offer substantial amounts (50% is a typical modal offer) Responders reject offers below 25% with high probability Universal behavior throughout the world Large degree of variability of offers among societies ( %)
15
Experimental results Extraordinary amount of data
Camerer, Behavioral Game Theory (Princeton University Press, 2003) Henrich et al. (eds.), Foundations of Human Sociality : Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies (Oxford University Press, 2004)
16
Experimental results Ultimatum game as an interpreting tool
Paciotti et al., American Scientist 93, 58 (2005)
17
Altruistic rewarding M -u +2v M +2u -v
(Fehr, Kirchsteiger & Riedl, 1993) experimenter M -u +2v M +2u -v truster trustee
18
Experimental results Both players gain the maximum by exchanging M
The trustee gains more by returning nothing So truster’s best strategy is to transfer nothing Results: More than 50% of trustees transfer money back, the more the higher the truster’s transfer Players often exchange M Universal behaviour throughout the world Homo economicus vs. Homo reciprocans Review in Fehr & Fischbacher, Nature 425, 785 (2003)
19
Strong reciprocity Explanations for altruistic behaviour:
Kin cooperation selfish genes Reciprocity tit-for-tat strategy (Axelrod’s experiments) Reputation gain altruism as sexual ornament (handicap principle) Strong reciprocity sense of fairness requires “other-regarding” capabilities
20
Strong reciprocity Importance of strong reciprocity:
In experiments of public goods, the presence of a few cheaters quickly deteriorates cooperation The introduction of a few altruistic punishers forces long term cooperation Strong reciprocity seems a crucial element to ensure cooperation in human societies
21
Strong reciprocity Evolutionary origins of strong reciprocity:
Standard answer: cultural evolution through group selection Evidences in favour: Strong variability between cultures in altruistic patterns Increase of altruistic behaviour in children as they grow Simulations of group selection models
22
Is group selection unavoidable?
Is evolutionary game theory correct?
23
Our model: setup ...... N players
A.S. & J. A. Cuesta, J. Theor. Biol., in press (2005) ...... N players player i ti : threshold (minimum share player i accepts) fi : fitness (accumulated capital) M monetary units (M=100)
24
Our model: game step tp tr tp tr ≥ < ...... N players tp tr fp fr
proposer responder tp fp tr fr +M-tp +tp tp tr < tp tr ≥
25
Our model: every s steps
...... N players new player minimum fitness maximum fitness tmin fmin t’max fmax tmax fmax +1 -1 (prob.=1/3) mutation: t’max= tmax
26
Implemented features Degree of altruism inherited from progenitor (with some error) No learning from experience No influence from other players (no culture) No groups Other-regarding behaviour with optimization (players offer the minimum they would accept) Fitness (accumulated capital) is inherited
27
Small populations N =1000, 107 games, s =1, uniform initial condition
28
Slow selection N =1000, 108 games, s =104, ti =1 initial condition
29
Large populations N =106, 2x107 games, s =1, uniform initial condition
30
Slow selection N =105, 1.28x1011 games, s =104, ti =1 initial condition
31
Why are reciprocators selected?
Higher threshold implies lower payoffs but higher acceptance rates for agent’s own offers The presence of altruistic punishers increases rejection of selfish agents’ offers Mutations are small (darwinian), so newborn altruistic agents are just a little more altruistic A quantitative description is still lacking
32
Two thresholds (s small)
N =1000, 106 games, s =1, uniform initial condition accept offer
33
Two thresholds (s middle)
N =1000, 108 games, s =1000, ti = ai =1 initial condition accept offer
34
Two thresholds (s large)
N =1000, 109 games, s =105, ti = ai =1 initial condition accept offer
35
Discussion Altruistic punishment is not necessarily a losing strategy when there are many agents Thus it may be established by individual selection alone Results reproduce the observed variability One or two levels: not important for the arising of altruistic punishment Mutation rate might be relevant
36
Mutation rate effect N =10000, 108 games, s =1, ti = 1 initial condition
37
Related results
38
Related results
39
Related results Stag-hunt game: S R
C. P. Roca, J. A. Cuesta & A. S., in progress (2005) Stag-hunt game: Two equilibria, S and R Round-robin gaming: S or R selected from x0 (x fraction of R) s games between death-birth S R
40
Related results
41
Related results Random death Death proportional to fitness
42
Discussion In general, evolutionary game theory studies a limit situation: s infinite! (every player plays every other one before selection) Number of games per player Poisson distributed Fluctuations may keep players with smaller ‘mean-field’ fitness alive
43
Further discussion Thresholds observed in neural activity measurements (Sanfey et al., 2003) (suggest that this threshold is an inheritable feature) Correlation with other-regarding behavior: also in different primates (capuchin monkeys) (Brosnan & de Waal, 2003)
44
Main conclusions Altruism (altruistic punishment, as implemented in the Ultimatum Game) need not be an evolutionary losing strategy, so it may have arisen through standard individual selection A new perspective in evolutionary game theory: more general dynamics, dictated by the specific application
45
Adam Smith on altruism How selfish soever man may be supposed, there are evidently some principles in his nature, which interest him in the fortunes of others, and render their happiness necessary to him, though he derives nothing from it, except the pleasure of seeing it. Adam Smith (The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 1854, Chapter 1)
Similar presentations
© 2025 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.