Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byDouglas Reed Modified over 6 years ago
1
World Development Report 2004 Making Services Work for Poor People
Qualidade do Gasto Publico no Brasil June 26-27, 2003 Ritva Reinikka Development Research Group, The World Bank
2
Messages Services are failing poor people. But they can work. How?
By empowering poor people to Monitor and discipline service providers Raise their voice in policymaking By strengthening incentives for service providers to serve the poor Too often, services are failing poor people—in access, quantity, quality, affortability. But governments, citizens and donors can make them work—by putting poor people at the center of service provision—in three ways: By empowering poor people: To monitor and discipline service providers Raise their voice in policymaking By strengthening incentives facing service providers to serve the poor.
3
MDGs—Global Aggregates
Universal Primary Education Eradicate Poverty & Hunger 1. We begin with the MDGs, and consider global aggregates only. For income poverty we are on track. Of course, this is because rapid growth in India and China, the two most populous countries, is reducing poverty at a rapid rate. This global aggregate doesn’t show that Africa is off-track on the poverty goal, too. [All these numbers come from the MDG website 2. But for the HD goals, we are seriously off track, even at the global level.
4
MDGs—Global Aggregates
Promote Gender Equality Reduce Child Mortality Ratio of girls to boys in primary and secondary school (%) Furthermore, we are off track because these aggregates are even worse for poor people. Not only are we falling short on these human development goals, but we need to invest in people to accelerate progress towards them. Why? Because growth—while necessary and the most important determinant—is not enough.
5
Outcomes are worse for poor people Cumulative deaths per 1000 births
Poorest quintile Richest Source: Analysis of Demographic and Health Survey data
6
Outcomes are worse for poor people Percent aged 15 to 19 completing each grade or higher
Poorest quintile Richest Why are these outcomes worse for poor people? Why are we falling short of the health and education goals? Is it simply because there has not been enough economic growth? Source: Analysis of Demographic and Health Survey data
7
Growth is not enough Percent living on $1/day
Primary completion rate (%) Under-5 mortality rate Target 2015 growth alone East Asia 14 4 100 19 26 Europe and Central Asia 1 15 Latin America 8 95 17 30 Middle East and North Africa 96 25 41 South Asia 22 99 43 69 Africa 24 35 56 59 151 If we look at how close we will come to reaching the MDGs based on growth alone, we find that: In five of the six regions we will reach the poverty goal. The only one we won’t is Africa. But relying on growth alone, we reach the education goal in only two regions. And we will hit the child mortality goal in none of the regions by relying on growth alone. Clearly, we will need more resources to accelerate progress in these areas. But we know that more resources—or more public spending for that matter—will not be enough. Governments need to improve the way they use their spending. Because services are failing poor people.
8
Increasing public spending is not enough
9
Increasing public spending is not enough
10
Similar changes in public spending can be associated with vastly different changes in outcomes
What this means is that countries that spend the same amount could have vastly different outcomes (e.g., Ethiopia and Malawi).
11
and vastly different changes in spending can be associated with similar changes in outcomes.
Conversely, countries with different spending patterns have similar outcomes.
12
How are services failing poor people?
Public spending usually benefits the rich, not the poor
13
Expenditure incidence
Health Education Percent to richest quintile poorest quintile If you look at health and education spending—usually thought to be pro-poor. In Guinea, 48 percent of public spending on health goes to the richest quintile, while less than 8 percent goes to the poorest. This is one of the areas where we updated the data (most recently available, credible studies) This anti-poor expenditure incidence is reflected in data about access to public facilities. Source: Compiled from various sources
14
How are services failing poor people?
Public spending usually benefits the rich, not the poor Money fails to reach frontline service providers In Uganda, only 13% of non-wage recurrent spending on primary education reached primary schools Even if we can improve the allocation of resources, and build facilities closer to poor people, there is a problem that the money doesn’t reach the frontline service provider.
15
How are services failing poor people?
Public spending benefits the rich more than the poor Money fails to reach frontline service providers Service quality is low for poor people And even if the money reaches the frontline provider, the incentives for delivering good quality services are weak. The clearest manifestation of this is the high levels of teacher and health-worker absenteeism we find in low-income countries.
16
Examples of low service quality
Bangladesh: Absenteeism rates for doctors in primary health care centers: 74%. Indonesia: Absenteeism in primary schools: 18%; in primary health clinics: 42%. Zimbabwe: 13% of respondents gave as a reason for not delivering babies in public facilities that “nurses hit mothers during delivery”. Guinea: 70% of government drugs disappeared. To understand these failures in service provision, as well as some of the success stories (which I will tell you about shortly), we need a framework.
17
But services can work Infant mortality and malnutrition reduced in Ceará, Brazil Citywide services in Johannesburg, South Africa reformed Cash transfers to households in Mexico increased enrollment, lowered illness cases Citizen report cards in Bangalore, India More money reached primary schools in Uganda A program in Ceara, by recruiting, training and deploying community health workers, and introducing the Ceara Municipal Seal of Approval award for “child-friendly” municipalities, reduced infant mortality from 100 per 1000 in 1980 to 27 per 1000 in 2001. In 1997, Johannesburg declared bankruptcy. They rationalized the many services—sold some (airport, produce market, etc.), contracted out waste management, sanitation, electricity, etc., and corporatized the zoo. By 2000, the city was solvent and services improved. PROGRESA , covering 40 percent of rural families in Mexico, lowered illness rates by 20 percent among children, and increased enrollment rates by 8 percentage points for girls, 5 for boys. An NGO introduced citizen report cards in Bangalore, which were widely publicized in the press, leading to a response from the state government. These cards have now been launched all over India, and in Ukraine, Philippines, Vietnam. The discovery that only 13 percent of the money reached primary schools led to a campaign that tracked the flow of funds monthly in the newspapers, accompanied by public announcements by Museveni, all of which helped double enrollments in Uganda.
18
A framework of relationships of accountability
The framework is very simple. Think about why there is no service delivery problem in shoes or vegetables or other competitive market transactions. The reason is that there is a clear system of accountability between the customer and the provider. The customer provides money, in return for the service. The customer can tell whether or not he has received the service. If he doesn’t like the service, he has several options—he can go elsewhere for his business next time (there is no repeat business), or he can seek legal recourse. And the point is that the provider knows this, and behaves accordingly. In the case of most services, society has decided not to use the traditional market mechanism to provide it. In this case, the customer—or client—can exert power over the provider (or hold the provider accountable) through indirect means:
19
A framework of relationships of accountability
We call this the long route of accountability. The client influences the policymaker (politician or bureaucrat), and the policymaker has to exert power over the provider. This “long route” is where services break down. But we can also strengthen them by strengthening the two relationships.
20
A framework of relationships of accountability
Let’s start with the citizen-policymaker link. Citizens can exert power over policymakers through elections, and through other means of expressing their “voice.” But even in democratic societies, the provision of (free or subsidized) public services becomes the currency of political patronage and clientelism. Politicians don’t locate pro-poor programs where poor people live necessarily; they locate it where people who vote for them live.
21
Mexico’s PRONASOL, Large social assistance program (1.2% of GDP) Water, sanitation, electricity and education construction to poor communities Limited poverty impact Reduced poverty by 3% If better targeted, could have reduced it by 64% In the late 1980s, Mexico introduced a social assistance program aimed at delivering services to the poor. But the program had a limited impact on poverty. Why? The bureaucrats chose to reward those municipalities that voted for the majority party, which was PRI.
22
This can be explained by looking at the amount of per-capita PRONASOL expenditures, according to the party that the municipality voted for. This can happen in democratic societies as well as one-party states. And it can work in both kinds (Cuba, China, Sri Lanka, Costa Rica). But the important lesson is that we need to be aware of whether or not the politics in the country will be “pro-rich” or “pro-poor” before designing service delivery mechanisms.
23
A framework This is a problem for two reasons:
The provider may not have incentives to provide the service. His pay is unaffected by whether or not he provides the service. Absenteeism rates in schools and clinics is an example of this. One way to improve upon this is to make the provider’s pay depend on the service—as in a contract. A good example is from Cambodia.
24
Policymaker-Provider: Contracting NGOs in Cambodia
Contracting out (CO): NGO can hire and fire, transfer staff, set wages, procure drugs, etc. Contracting in (CI): NGO manages district, cannot hire and fire (but can transfer staff), $0.25 per capita budget supplement Control/Comparison (CC): Services run by government 12 districts randomly assigned to CC, CI or CO An example of where this was overcome is in post-civil-war Cambodia. The government needed to get a health program going in a hurry. So they decided to experiment with three different types of arrangements, two of which used NGOs. In fact, they used two different types of contracts, namely contracting out—where the NGO can use whichever staff they desire; and contracting in, where they NGO had to use existing staff, but could manage them as they wished. Finally, and importantly, they had a control group where the services were run by the government. Before showing the results of this exercise, I want to point out that the Cambodian government decided to randomly assign districts to the different arrangements. This was an explicit case where the government wanted to be able to learn from the experiment in a systematic way. This is an example of a more general theme that is recurring in the WDR. If we are to scale up, we need to be able to learn from these service-delivery innovations in a systematic way.
25
Utilization of Facilities by Poor People Sick in last month, %
The results are quite dramatic. But contracting out is not always feasible. For one thing, you cannot specify exactly everything in a contract. You can’t specify exactly what teachers teach in the classroom, or what the doctor does in the clinic. In fact, it could be unproductive to do so (as when Parisian taxi drivers bring traffic to a halt in the French capital by following the rules exactly). In this case, you could choose providers who will have an incentive to serve the poor. Faith-based NGOs in Uganda work for 28% lower salary, but provide better quality health services than the public clinics. But the bottom line is that policymakers can best get the incentives right when they can monitor the service provider’s actions and results. When they can’t monitor, however, we should remember that the client can often be the monitor. So we may want to return to the short route of accountability.
26
A framework Finally, we turn to the relationship we started with, the “short route”—between client and provider. For even though these are non-market transactions, there may be ways to increase the client’s power over the provider by giving him increased choice and the chance to participate.
27
FSSAP Bangladesh Criteria:
Attendance in school Passing grade Unmarried Girls to receive scholarship deposited to account set up in her name School to receive support based on # of girls This program has not been evaluated yet, but initial results are impressive. Secondary enrolment for girls is rising faster than for boys in Bangladesh. Single-sex schools are cropping up. And other schools are building separate latrines for girls and boys. The FSSAP shows two things. First, that clients are heterogeneous. [Just like the poor are heterogeneous]. Girls have different preferences—for single-sex schools, separate latrines. Giving clients are choice enables those preferences to get revealed. Second, giving clients a choice disciplines the provider to provide the service. What this tells us is that no single service delivery mechanism—privatization, central-government provision—will work in all circumstances. But does anything go? No, in fact, our framework tells us that certain arrangements will work in certain circumstances. And what those circumstances are. While no one size fits all, perhaps eight sizes do.
28
Decentralization We call this the long route of accountability.
The client influences the policymaker (politician or bureaucrat), and the policymaker has to exert power over the provider. This “long route” is where services break down. But we can also strengthen them by strengthening the two relationships.
29
Client-Provider: EDUCO Program in El Salvador
Parents’ associations (ACEs) Hire and fire teachers Visit schools on regular basis Contract with Ministry of Education to deliver primary education
30
EDUCO promoted parental involvement…
EDUCO promoted parental involvement… …which boosted student performance (% increase in test scores per visit)
31
EDUCO Effect: School days missed due to teacher absence
Avg # of days missed: 1.34 Despite the much higher levels of teacher experience in traditional schools, they are pad the same. This reflects the fact that on afverage, for the same expereince, EDUCO teachers are paid more -- but they have less tenure
32
What not to do Leave it to the private sector
Simply increase public spending Apply technocratic solutions
33
What is to be done? Expand information
Tailor service delivery arrangements to service characteristics and country circumstances These examples have highlighted the role of information—in helping citizens raise their voice, in enabling policymakers to monitor providers and learning about better client-provider innovations. So information may be one thing we could do even when all else fails. Information is important for another reason. We can’t get by with one innovation here, another one there.
34
Eight sizes fit all? Difficult to monitor Easy to monitor
35
Eight sizes fit all? Difficult to monitor Easy to monitor
Heterogeneous clients Homogeneous clients Emphasizes the heterogeneity of poor people (disabled, women)
36
Eight sizes fit all? Difficult to monitor Easy to monitor
Heterogeneous clients Pro-rich politics Pro-poor politics Homogeneous clients And the politics
37
Eight sizes fit all? Difficult to monitor Easy to monitor
Heterogeneous clients Pro-rich politics Pro-poor politics Homogeneous clients Government provision or contracting Let’s consider two polar opposite. If the service is easy to monitor (e.g., vaccinations), the government is pro-poor (such as Cuba or Costa Rica or Sri Lanka), and the clients are relatively homogeneous (such as Norway), then central-government provision will work (as will any other arrangement). But if the service is difficult to monitor, such as school teaching, the clients are heterogeneous, and there is evidence of political patronage, such as education in India, then demand-side interventions (such as FSSAP in Bangladesh) coupled with increasing the power of citizens to monitor the provider, such as EDUCO, may yield better results.
38
Eight sizes fit all? Difficult to monitor Easy to monitor
Heterogeneous clients Pro-rich politics Pro-poor politics Homogeneous clients Central-government provision Government provision or contracting Let’s consider two polar opposite. If the service is easy to monitor (e.g., vaccinations), the government is pro-poor (such as Cuba or Costa Rica or Sri Lanka), and the clients are relatively homogeneous (such as Norway), then central-government provision will work (as will any other arrangement). But if the service is hard to monitor (such as student learning), then with homogeneous population and pro-poor politics, you may want to have government provision. This is the situation in Scandinavia. Example of homogeneous becoming heterogeneous—immigrants in Sweden. But if the service is difficult to monitor, such as school teaching, the clients are heterogeneous, and there is evidence of political patronage, such as education in India, then demand-side interventions (such as FSSAP in Bangladesh) coupled with increasing the power of citizens to monitor the provider, such as EDUCO, may yield better results.
39
Eight sizes fit all? Difficult to monitor Easy to monitor
Heterogeneous clients Pro-rich politics Demand-side subsidies, co-payments by households Pro-poor politics Homogeneous clients Central-government provision Government provision or contracting But if the service is difficult to monitor, such as school teaching, the clients are heterogeneous, and there is evidence of political patronage, such as education in India, then demand-side interventions (such as FSSAP in Bangladesh) coupled with increasing the power of citizens to monitor the provider, such as EDUCO, may yield better results. So what does this imply for action? We took your advice and made some bold claims in the report. I’d like to share some of those. Without bold actions, we won’t have scaling up.
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com. Inc.
All rights reserved.