Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Market Inefficiencies: Externalities and Public Goods

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Market Inefficiencies: Externalities and Public Goods"— Presentation transcript:

1 Market Inefficiencies: Externalities and Public Goods
7 Market Inefficiencies: Externalities and Public Goods

2 Midterm Exam Maximum score: 80, 88.89 % Average score: 60.6, 67.35 %
80% and above: 7 70%-80%: 5 60%-70%: 20 Below 60%: 2 Did you see your grade, posted on D2L. How do you feel? Do you feel satisfied with your grade? I know you can do better. Work harder. Be careful in some questions.

3 Previously Consumer surplus is the difference between what a consumer is willing to pay and the price actually paid for a good or service. Producer surplus is the difference between the minimum price a producer is willing to accept and the payments he actually receives from selling a good. Excise taxes create deadweight loss and reduce overall economic welfare. Lecture notes: we examined how markets allocate scarce resources with the forces of supply and demand, and we saw that the equilibrium of supply and demand is typically an efficient allocation of resources. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity. Markets do many things well, but they do not do everything well. We examine why markets sometimes fail to allocate resources efficiently, how government policies can potentially improve the market’s allocation, and what kinds of policies are likely to work best. This chapter will also deal with economic welfare. Specifically, we will study situations where certain costs or benefits are not internalized by the parties involved in trade. This can lead to an inefficient level of goods being traded.

4 Big Questions What are externalities, and how do they affect markets?
What are private goods and public goods? What are the challenges of providing non-excludable goods?

5 Externalities Externality is the uncompensated impact of one person’s actions on the well-being of a bystander. Negative externality cost Positive externality benefit Lecture notes: Examples: driving a car. Cigarette. Pollution. Smile, barking dogs, beautiful gardens. Research in technology (it creates knowledge that other people can use.). Education, vaccine. Examples? Do you create externalities on others? Positive or negative? Smile. Sleep, snoring Consider an oil refinery. The oil refinery imposes a negative externality (pollution) on nearby residents. This can cause sickness, breathing problems, and dirty clothes.

6 Externalities Internal costs (benefit) External costs (benefit)
The costs of an activity paid by an individual engaging in the activity External costs (benefit) The cost of an activity paid for by someone else not directly involved in the activity Social costs (benefit) Sum of internal and external costs Lecture notes: To be more precise, we use internal, external cost to illustrate externality. Examples: driving a car. Cigarette. Pollution. Consider driving a car. Internal costs: you pay for gas, car maintenance, wear and tear on vehicle. External costs: you create pollution and road congestion. Consider eating a garlic-filled Italian meal at a restaurant. Internal costs: you pay for the meal; cost you time and money. External costs: you may create unpleasantness to others later with bad garlic breath. driving a car. Cigarette. Pollution. Smile, barking dogs, beautiful gardens. Research in technology (it creates knowledge that other people can use.).

7 Third-Party Problem Externalities Third-Party Problems
Occur when private cost (or benefit) diverges from social cost (or benefit) Third-Party Problems People not directly involved in activity experience positive or negative externalities. Lecture notes: Third party = “other person” who is not involved directly in the activity, but suffers the cost of the activity. Pollution and secondhand smoke are examples. Externalities: think “external.”

8 Third-Party Problem Negative externalities Positive externalities
Costs experienced by third parties “Too much” of the good is consumed and produced. Pollution, secondhand smoke Positive externalities Benefits experienced by third parties “Not enough” of the good is consumed and produced. Education, vaccines Lecture tips: Generally, these are all examples of “market failures.” This occurs when individuals do not consider (internally) all of the costs or benefits of an activity. With a negative externality, there are external costs (borne by others) that the individual engaging in the activity does not consider. Thus, social costs are understated, and too much of the activity is done. With a positive externality, there are external benefits (borne by third parties) that the individual engaging in the activity does not consider. Thus, social benefits are understated, and too little of the activity is done.

9 Correcting for Externalities
Internalizing the externality The individual involved in the activity takes account for social costs (or benefits). For negative externalities: Force individual to pay for external costs Tax production Regulate production Overall output is reduced, illustrated by a leftward shift in supply. Lecture notes: Consider an oil refinery. The oil refinery imposes a negative externality (pollution) on nearby residents. This can cause sickness, breathing problems, and dirty clothes. When a negative externality exists, the government may be able to restore the social optimum by forcing externality—causing market participants to pay for the cost of their actions. In this case, there are three potential solutions. First, the refiner can be required to install pollution abatement equipment or to change production techniques to reduce emissions. A tax could be levied as a disincentive to produce. Finally, the government could require that the firm pay for any environmental damage it creates. Each of these solutions forces the firm to internalize the externality, meaning that the firm pays for the externality in some way. Remember that the supply curve can be thought of as the MC (marginal cost) curve. A leftward shift means that we are internalizing high costs of production, and will want to produce less of the good.

10 Correcting for Negative Externalities
Image: Animated Figure 7.1 Lecture notes: Intuition: the new supply curve (shifted to the left) reflects ALL the costs (not just internal). Higher costs mean less production. The figure illustrates the contrast between the market equilibrium and the social optimum in the case of an oil refinery. These costs are indicated on the graph by the supply curve, S internal, which represents how much the oil refiner will produce if it does not have to pay for the negative consequences of its activity. In this situation, the market equilibrium, Em, accounts only for the internal costs of production. Suppose now the firm has to pay for pollution somehow (tax, pay for environment damages, or install abatement equipment). Abatement = act of reducing pollution. Having to pay the costs of imposing pollution on others reduces the amount of the pollution-causing activity. This result is seen in the shift of the supply curve to S social. The new supply curve reflects a combination of the internal and external costs of producing the good. Since each of the corrective measures requires the refiner to spend money to correct the externality, the willingness to sell the good declines, or shifts left. The result is a social optimum at a lower quantity, Qs, than at the market equilibrium, Qm. Here the trade-off is clear. We can reduce negative externalities by requiring producers to internalize the externality. However, internalizing the externality is not without cost. Since the supply curve shifts left, the quantity produced will be lower. In the real world, there is always a cost. In addition, when there is an externality, the market equilibrium creates deadweight loss, as shown by the yellow triangle in the figure.

11 Correcting for Externalities
For positive externalities: Help individuals realize external benefits Finance and/or subsidize production and consumption of the good Laws requiring consumption Vaccines Education Overall consumption is increased, illustrated by a rightward shift in demand Lecture notes: Generally, with positive externalities, we know that there are external benefits that individuals may not account for. Thus, we want to increase resource allocation to the activity. Remember that the demand curve can be thought of as the MB (marginal benefit) curve. Shifting this curve to the right can be thought of as us realizing the extra benefits, so we want to engage in more of this activity. Laws requiring consumption: everyone has to go to school until the age of 16. Some schools require vaccination records.

12 Correcting for Positive Externalities
Image: Animated Figure 7.2 Lecture tip: Use flu shots as an example of a behavior with a positive externality. Easy intuition: the new demand curve (shifted to the right) reflects ALL the benefits rather than just internal benefits. There is an incentive for people in high risk groups to get vaccinated for the sake of their own health. Looking at the figure, we capture this internal benefit in the demand curve labeled D internal. However, the market equilibrium, Em, only accounts for the internal benefits of individuals getting vaccinated. In order to maximize the health benefits for everyone, public health officials need to find a way to encourage as many people as possible to get vaccinated. One way is through school vaccination laws. These laws require that all children entering school provide proof of vaccination against a variety of diseases. The overall effect of child vaccination laws are that more people get vaccinated early in life, which reduces the spread of contagious diseases. This creates a positive externality for society. Government can also promote the social optimum by encouraging economic activity that helps third parties. For example, it can offer a subsidy, or price break, to encourage more people to get vaccinated. The subsidy acts as a consumption incentive. Since the subsidy allows the consumer to spend less money, the willingness to get the vaccine increases. More people are immunized, a result seen in a shift of the demand curve in the figure from D internal to D social. The new demand curve reflects the sum of the internal and social benefits of getting the vaccination. The subsidy encourages consumers to internalize the externality and, as a result, consumption moves from the market equilibrium, Qm, to a social optimum at a higher quantity, Qs.

13 Summary of Externalities
Negative Positive Definition Costs borne by third parties. Benefits received by third parties. Examples Oil refining creates air pollution. Traffic congestion causes all motorists to spend more time on the road waiting. Airports create noise pollution. Flu shots prevent the spread of disease. Education citizens are more productive and make more informed decisions for the betterment of society. Restored Historic buildings enable people to enjoy the beautiful architectural details. Corrective measures Taxes, charges, or regulations Subsidies or government provision Lecture tip: Click through to reveal the table cells. We have seen that markets do not handle externalities well. With a negative externality, the market produces too much of a good. But in the case of a positive externality, the market does not produce enough.

14 Property Rights Externalities often arise because of a lack of clearly defined property rights. Ask: Who owns the air? Can I pollute? Private property Provides exclusive right of ownership that allows for the use and exchange of property Creates incentive to maintain, protect, and conserve property, as well as listen to the wishes of others Lecture notes: We will discuss each of these incentives, one at a time, on the next slide.

15 Private Property Incentives
Incentive to maintain Keep the vehicle safe and reliable Incentive to protect Lock your doors Incentive to conserve Extend vehicle life, drive less Incentive to trade with others You can voluntarily trade for something better in the market. Lecture tips: In this slide, use a car as an example of a privately owned good. Ask your students the question: What do you take better care of? Public restroom or your own private bathroom? Your own car or the public bus? (Do you wipe your feet before getting into both?) Your own bike or equipment at the gym? Just get the students to realize that when you privately own something, you have more incentives to take good care of the good!

16 Coase Theorem Two adjacent farmers, no fences
One raising cattle One growing wheat Scenario 1: The cattle rancher is liable for damages the cows cause. Options for cattle rancher Put up a fence Pay damages to wheat farmer Rancher will consider costs of both to make choice. Lecture notes: Assume the cattle cause damage to the ground (no matter what farmer the ground belongs to). Without a fence, the cattle roam over both lands. If the cost of the fence (building, maintenance) is more than the cost of the cattle damage, the rancher will not build a fence, and will just pay the farmer for damages. If the cattle destruction cost is greater, the rancher will build a fence to keep the cattle on his own land. Either result will force the cattle farmer to internalize the entire costs of the cattle damage.

17 Coase Theorem Scenario 2: The wheat farmer does not have a legal right to cattle-free fields. Options for farmer Put up a fence Accept occasional cattle damage Result? If property rights are fully specified, either the cattle rancher or wheat farmer will build a fence. Coase theorem If there are no barriers to negotiations, interested parties will bargain to correct any externality. Lecture notes: If the cost of the fence (building, maintenance) is more than the cost of the cattle damage, the farmer will not build a fence, and will just accept the damages to the wheat. If the cattle destruction cost is greater, the farmer will build a fence to keep the cattle out. Building the fence will force the cattle rancher to internalize the externality. Coase determined that whenever the size of the externality is large enough to justify the expense, the externality gets internalized. As long as the property rights are fully specified, either the cattle rancher or wheat farmer will build a fence. The fence keeps the cattle away from the wheat, removes the externality, and avoids the destruction of property. No government intervention needed.

18 Private Goods Characteristics of certain consumption goods Excludable
The good must be purchased before use. Rival The good cannot be enjoyed by more than one person at the same time. Private goods Are both excludable and rival in consumption Most goods we purchase and consume are private goods. Lecture notes: Most goods we purchase and consume are private goods. A private good is both excludable and rival in consumption. For instance, a slice of pizza is excludable because it must be purchased before you can eat it. Also, a slice of pizza is rival; only one person can eat it. These two characteristics: excludability and rivalry, allow the market to work efficiently in the absence of externalities. Consider a pizza business. The pizzeria bakes pizza pies because it knows it can sell them to consumers. Likewise, consumers are willing to buy pizza because it is a food they enjoy. Since the producer is able to charge a price and the consumer to acquire a rival good, this sets the stage for mutual gains from trade.

19 Public Goods Public goods Free-rider problem Can be consumed by many
Difficult to exclude non-payers from consumption Examples: Public defense, public parks, public fireworks display Free-rider problem Someone has the ability to receive the benefit of a good without paying for it. Eating (and not paying) at a free-will donation meal Letting a classmate do all the work in a group project! Lecture tip: Other free-rider example: not putting money in a collection plate!

20 Club Goods, Common Resources
Non-rival and excludable Examples: Satellite TV, gym membership Common resource goods Rival but non-excludable Fishing, hunting (specific animals fished and hunted), public campsites Lecture notes: Club goods: You can be excluded if you don’t pay. However, they are non-rival. Just because I get a membership to the YMCA doesn’t exclude you from getting one. Common resources: You can’t be excluded from the public campsite, but they are rival campsites. If I set up my tent at campsite 1A, you can’t also set up camp there. There are a limited number of campsites, as well as deer to hunt. Technicality: hunting and fishing sometimes requires licensing and fees, and that could sometimes exclude.

21 Lecture notes: Photo of crowded beach. Public goods or what ? Common pool resource If there are THIS MANY people at the beach, you’ll definitely notice.

22 Four Types of Goods Consumption Rival Non-rival Excludable Yes
Private Goods pizza, watches, automobiles Club Goods satellite television, education, country clubs No Common Resource Goods Alaskan king crab, sharing a large popcorn at the movies, congested roads, charitable giving Public Goods street performers, defense, Tsunami warning systems Lecture tip; Click through to remove the white rectangles to reveal the table one cell at a time. 2x2 grid here. Are goods excludable? (yes or no) Is consumption rival or non-rival?

23 Public Goods Game This is a simple card game. Each of you will be given four cards, two of these cards are red (hearts or diamonds), and two of these cards are black (clubs or spades). You will be grouped with 4 other students. The exercise will consist of a number of rounds. When a round begins, I will come to each of group in order, and you will play two of your four cards by placing these two cards face down on top of the stack in my hand. Your earnings in dollars are determined by what you do with your red cards. Black cards placed on the stack have no effect on the count. For each red card that you keep you will earn 4 dollars. For each red card I collect, everyone in the group will earn 2 dollars. earnings = $4 times the # of red cards you kept + $2 times the total # of red cards I collect in your group. After round 5, I will announce a change in the earnings for each red card you keep. I will announce another change after round 10 and we will complete another 5 rounds. What decision? What strategy are used? = more contribution, In a given round, an individual can maximize monetary earnings by not contributing, but earnings for the group as a whole are maximized when everyone contributes fully in this case, market can’t efficiently allocate resources. Characteristics of red cards? Public goods? the characteristics of a public good: non-excludability and non-rivalry. In the classroom card game, individuals cannot be excluded from the benefits of contributions, and one person’s earnings from the group contribution do not reduce anyone else’s earnings. Contribute same among 3 treatments? Factors may foster cooperation? Eg, university fund-raising campaigns. Higher contribution cost? situations in which people might have different contribution costs, think of institutions that are (or could be) used to increase contributions toward public goods. This can lead to a discussion of cases in which government intervention may be desirable, e.g., tax incentives for charitable giving or government provision of the public good. Pattern? Less and less contribution. Individuals are often more willing to contribute when they believe these contributions will be matched by others.

24 (In the remaining rounds, $ per red card kept = $3.)
# red cards kept $ per red card kept earnings for cards kept $2* total # red cards in stack your total earnings 1 2 3 4 5 (In the remaining rounds, $ per red card kept = $3.) 6 7 8 9 10 with communication 11 12 13 14 15 Earnings Record Sheet

25 Tragedy of the Commons Tragedy of the commons Original example:
Occurs when a rival (but non-excludable) good becomes depleted or ruined Original example: Garret Hardin, Science Magazine, 1968 Cattle grazing Commons = shared area that all cattle farmers get to use to let cattle graze Lecture notes: Tragedy of the commons, means for common resource goods, tragedy can happen. For example, a pasture. It can sustain a limited amount of cattle; it needs to sustain itself over time. While if too many cattle grazed in the pasture at the same time, this pasture become depleted and ruined.

26 Tragedy of the Commons The commons can be sustained indefinitely with a capacity of around 100 cows. Suppose 100 farmers are each allowed to have 1 cow freely graze in the commons. One farmer thinks: What if I bring 2 cows? 100 cows? 101 cows? No difference! But suppose that ALL the farmers are thinking the same thing? Can the commons support 200 cows? Lecture tip: The pictures are set on a timer. The slide will slowly fill up with cows. Each additional cow may not make a noticeable difference, but soon you will begin to notice all the cows! The slide will fill up after 50 seconds. The pasture will be depleted

27 Tragedy The commons get destroyed, even though this was in nobody’s best interest. Lecture notes: The pasture will be depleted Here is the tragedy: Everyone did what they thought was in their own best interest: bring a second cow. I get twice as much free feeding, and the costs are minimal (to me and society). However, if EVERYONE does this, all those “small” costs add up to a “big” cost! The commons dies, which is bad for everyone.

28 Economics in South Park
Tragedy of the commons: peeing in the pool If one person pees in the pool, the effect may be insignificant. But what if everyone does it? Economics in the Media Lecture tip: The clip mentioned on the slide can be found in the Interactive Instructor’s Guide. Access the direct link by clicking the icon in the PowerPoint above.

29 Common Property Incentives
Incentive to neglect Good cannot be protected. No political borders or ownership. Incentive to overuse Each individual wants to fish as much as possible for higher profits. If one conserves, others will fish even more. Incentive to ignore others No one has the ability to define how many resources can be used. I may still break the rules set even if others follow them. Lecture notes: The common property incentives are almost the opposite of the private property incentives!! Use cod fishing industry as an example. If you are a fisher, the whole ocean is a common resource. No borders on the ocean. If there’s no fish here, you’ll fish somewhere else. You will fish as much as you can. More fishing is more profit. Even if others are following the rules set in place, it’s still in my best interest to try and fish more to get a bigger haul. (Everyone is thinking the same thing.) Your behavior has negative externality on others.

30 Solution to the Tragedy of the Commons
General proactive management is needed. Taxes, regulations, or other ways to internalize a negative externality Lecture notes: In addition, there has to be a way to enforce the laws, as well as stating clear punishments for rule breakers.

31 Cap and Trade Cap and trade Good in theory, but negative consequences?
A system of pollution “permits” that are traded on an open market Purpose: reduce pollution Good in theory, but negative consequences? Agreements are difficult to negotiate; no international consensus Countries with restrictions have higher costs than others Lecture notes: Set a cap and trade. Pollution is a negative externality—a byproduct of manufacturing various goods. Difficulty: if the United States places tougher pollution standards on firms and other countries don’t, we are putting ourselves at a disadvantage. Other countries will produce cheaper products. Thus, cap and trade may only work successfully if the system (and trading market) was international. This would be very difficult to negotiate and organize. Thus, it is often called “cap and tax” since it seems to tax producers.

32 Conclusion Inefficiencies occur because of poor incentives
Externalities Arise from the result of diverging social and private costs (or benefits) Can be corrected by forcing economic agents to internalize them Public goods present a special challenge for a free-market economy. Lecture notes: One solution is to encourage businesses to internalize externalities. This can be done through taxes and regulations that force producers to account for the negative externalities that they create. Similarly, subsidies can spur the additional production of activities that generate positive externalities. However, not all externalities require active management from the government. Many externalities are too small to matter, and do not justify the costs associated with government regulation or taxation.

33 Summary Internal costs are costs that are directly borne by the decision-maker. Social costs = internal costs + external costs An externality exists whenever an internal cost, or benefit, diverges from a social cost, or benefit.

34 Summary When a negative externality exists:
Government can restore the social optimum by discouraging economic activity that harms third parties. When a positive externality exists: Government can restore the social optimum by increasing economic activity that benefits third parties. An externality is internalized when decision-makers take into account the external effects of their actions.

35 Summary Private property Under a system of common property:
Ensures that owners have an incentive to maintain, protect, and conserve their property, and also to trade it to others. Under a system of common property: The incentive structure causes destruction, neglect, and overuse. Tragedy of the commons may occur. The Coase theorem If there are no barriers to negotiations, and property rights are fully specified, interested parties will bargain privately to correct externalities.

36 Summary A public good has two characteristics:
It is non-excludable and non-rival in consumption. It creates the free-rider problem and results in the underproduction of the good in the market. The line between each of the four types of goods (private, club, common resource, and public) is often hard to distinguish. Economists use cost-benefit analysis to determine whether the benefits of providing one type of good outweighs the costs.

37 Practice What You Know Which of the following activities would most likely create a negative externality? eating a slice of pizza smoking a cigarette taking a nap getting a college degree Clicker Question Correct answer: B Secondhand smoke is a classic example of a negative externality. Third parties who are not smoking experience a cost.

38 Practice What You Know Which of the following activities is most likely to create a positive externality? eating a slice of pizza smoking a cigarette taking a nap getting a college degree Clicker Question Correct answer: D If you are more educated, other people around may be likely to experience external benefits. You may be more productive, less likely to be unemployed, and may be more politically involved.

39 Practice What You Know Membership at your local fitness facility is what type of good? private good club good common resource good public good Clicker Question Correct answer: B It’s excludable (you have to pay to be a member), but non-rival. Just because one person is a member doesn’t mean you can’t join as well.

40 Practice What You Know Suppose good X creates a negative externality. Which of the following would NOT be an appropriate way to correct the negative externality? subsidize the production of good X tax the production of good X limit how much of good X can be produced require the producers of good X to pay for external costs that arise Clicker Question Correct answer: A Subsidizing would result in MORE of good X being produced. We want less of the good to be made since it creates the negative externality.

41 Practice What You Know Which of the following is an example of a public good? a free outdoor Christmas light display a college football game a parking spot with a parking meter a college education Clicker Question Correct answer: A For (A) to be correct, note that the word “free” is explicitly included. Imagine a display, outdoors, that anyone can freely see and enjoy. The parking spot is not free, and is rivalrous. College education is not free (at least in the U.S.)


Download ppt "Market Inefficiencies: Externalities and Public Goods"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google